Toggle menu
Toggle personal menu
Not logged in
Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits.

Library:Great Victory in Agricultural Co-operativization in DPRK: Difference between revisions

From ProleWiki, the proletarian encyclopedia
More languages
(Created)
Tag: Visual edit
 
(Created)
Tag: Visual edit
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Library work|title=Great Victory in Agricultural Co-operativization in DPRK|author=Kim Han Joo|written in=1959|publisher=Foreign Languages Publishing House|source=[https://archive.org/details/great-victory-in-agricultural-co-operativization-in-dprk/mode/2up Internet Archive]}}
{{Library work|title=Great Victory in Agricultural Co-operativization in DPRK|author=Kim Han Joo|written in=1959|publisher=Foreign Languages Publishing House|source=[https://archive.org/details/great-victory-in-agricultural-co-operativization-in-dprk/mode/2up Internet Archive]}}
[[Category:Empty library pages]]
 
== Foreword ==
The historica] cause of agricultural co-operativization
was viccoriousiy carried out in our country in only four or
five years after the task of the socialist transformation of
agriculture had been set forth at the 6th Pienum of the
C.C. of the Workers’ Party of Korea convened immediately
after the truce.
 
Having completely healed the severe war wounds in a
short space of time by relying on the advantageous co-
operative economy, our agriculture is now making rap‘d
advance.
 
The question of food which was most difficult in the
early days following the truce and the prob:em of poor
peasants, the most urgent ones at that time, have been
completely solved, doing away with the source of exploita-
tion and poverty once and for all in the countrys:de.
 
The agr:cultural policy of our Party in the posi-libera-
tion days is a siriking demonstration of the correctness of
Marxism-Leninism which teaches us that the land reform,
a task of bourgeois democratic revolution, is no more than
the first step for solving the question of peasants, though
it is of great historic significance, and that revo:ution in
the countryside must be pushed up to a higher stage so as
to carry out the agricuitural co-operativization, a task ol
socialist revo.ution, for the final solution of the question.
 
Lenin said: “Such great changes in the life of tens of
millions of people, affecting the deep foundation of I?fe and
custom, as the changing from small-scale, ind‘vidual peasant
economy to the joint cultivation of land, can be brought
 
 
5
 
 
about only through long-drawn efforts andin_ general
they take place only when the people are forced by neces-
sity to rebuild their life.’ (Collected Works of Lenin,
Russian Ed., Vol. 28, p. 318)
 
In our country, too, preparations for agricultural co-
operativization had been fully made in line with the correct
agricultural policy of the Party after liberation, and the
movement for its realization started at a time when desire
of the peasants for it became more urgent.
 
So it made unprecedentedly rapid progress, and was
completed in a short space of time without a hitch,
 
The great achievement attained in the socialist
transformation of agriculture means the victory of the
agricultural policy our Party has consistently pursued
since liberation.
 
== Preparatory Stage of Agricultural Co-operativization ==
Until liberation, Korea remained a backward colonial,
semi-feudal agricultural country.
 
Japanese imperialists and a smal] number of land-
lords, only some 100,000 households, or 3-4 per cent of the
total peasant households, owned 2,600,000 jungbo of land,
or 60 per cent of the total arable land. While most of the
peasants, 2,400,000 peasant households with little or no
land, or 80 per cent of the total peasant households, were
tenant farmers under the condition of semi-serfdom, Farm
rent usually exceeded 50 per cent of the harvest, and some-
times it reached 70-80 per cent. More than 70 per cent of
the peasant households ran out of food for three or four
months every year, while less than 20 per cent of the peas-
ant households had sufficient food.
 
 
The capitalist sector in agriculture found its expres-
sion somewhat only in some fruit growing, livestock breed-
ing and ginseng cultivation. The rich peasant economy
also was insignificant and most of the rich peasants as-
sumed the character of semi-landlords.
 
 
The merciless exploitation by the Japanese imperialisis
and feudal landlords inevitably brought about a general
standstill of the agricuitural produciive forces and the im-
poverishment of toiling peasants.
 
The deep-rooted contradiction in the countryside con-
stituted one of the major causes which led the Korean peo-
ple to the anti-imperialist, anti-feudal national liberation
struggle. The land and peasant question was a most im-
portant question in our revolution.
 
 
Consequently, it was taken up as a most important re-.
volutionary task in the Ten-point Programme of the
Fatherland Restoration Association which was organized
and led by Comrade Kim I] Sung and other staunch Com-
munisis. Greatly inspired by th’s programme the broad
peasant masses in Korea, together with the progressive
work:ng class, rose up more valiantly in the anti-imperial-
ist, anti-feudal national liberation struggle.
 
 
However, until the country was I'berated by the great
Soviet Army, the merciless colonial plunder and feudal ex-
ploitation had continued in the countryside and the peas-
ants had not been abie to secure land and freedom.
 
Foilow:ng the historic August 15 Liberation, the Kore-
an peop:e were provided with conditions enabling them to
tae eee independent country in accordance with
 
eir will.
 
 
After liberation, under the guidance of the Workers’
Parity of Korea, the tasks of anti-imperialist, anti-feudal
democratic revoiution were successfully carried out in
North Korea where favourable conditions were provided by
the presence of the Soviet Army and the country’s economy
was put on a new footing.
 
 
The Land Reform carried out in March 1946 was of
great importance for promoting the country’s revoiution.
Land owned by the Japanese, Japanese organizations, pro-
Japanese, national traitors and the Korean landowners in
excess of 5 jungbo, and all the land not tilled by the own-
ers were confiscated without compensation. The confiscated
land was distributed without compensation to the hired
farm hands and the peasants who owned litt!e or no land.
The number of work-hands and family members determined
the sizes of piots in distribution. Abou! one million jungbo
or 53.8 per cent of the total arabie land was confiscated, of
which over 980,000 jungbo was distributed to 720,000 toil-
ing peasant households.
 
 
Although the land was not nationalized, it must be
pointed out that the land reform was most drastic in the
method of confiscation and distribution.
 
 
8
 
 
Owing to the land reform, not only about 30,000 land-
lords were liquidated as a class but the landlord-like rich
peasants were hit hard. The proportion of rich peasants
which had accounted for about 5 per cent of the entire peas-
ant househo'ds was decreased to 2-3 per cent. The colonial,
feudal landownership was thoroughly liquidated and the
land was given to the toiling peasants in conformity with
the principle, “tillers shall own land.”
 
 
At the time when the land reform was carr‘ed out, the
land owned by the state—the land owned by the People’s
Commitiees—was only 18,000 jungbo or less than one per
cent of the total arabte land. |
 
 
It was eloquent proof, first of all, that the Party and
the people’s power took into consideration above everything
else the toiling peasants’ urgent desire for, and interest in,
the land reform. It also showed that theze existed no large
scare cap‘talist economy in our agriculture which could
be turned into -state farms. Oniy about 2,700 jungbo of
orchards confiscated from landiords was all that con-
stituted the major material foundation of state-owned soci-
alist agriculture in our couniry.
 
 
Since there was no large-scale Junker economy in
Korea in the pre-libevation days, let alone modern capital-
ist agriculture, very few farm implements and draught
animals were confiscated. Only the irrigation facilities
confiscated from the Japanese imperial'sts and landiords
were all which came into the ownership of the State and
came into the use of the peasanis.
 
 
In short, some confiscated orchards and irrigation faci-
I'ties constituted the material foundation for the socialist
sec‘or in the field of agriculture immediately after the land
reform.
 
 
Accordingly, nothing like a co-operative economy
could be expected at the time. This is quite understandabie.
 
Small commodity economy, based on the land owner-
ship of the toiling peasanis, was dominant in our agricul-
ture. It can be seen more clearly in the following table:
 
[table]
 
Following the land reform, nationalization of major
industries was put into effect in August 1946 in the nor-
thern part of the country. As a result, industry, transport,
communications, banks, etc. formerly owned by Japanese
imperialists and comprador capitalists were, unlike in the
field of agriculture, put under the state ownership, that is,
the ownersh’p of the entire people. Consequently, the ratio
of the socialist economic sector became predominant in these
fields, doing away with the relations of capitalist exploita-
tion.
 
In industry, the private capitalist elements held an
insignificant position and the co-operative economic sector
came into being and began to grow.
 
[table]
 
Thus, the people’s democratic system established
through the democratic reforms after liberation was put
on two different economic foundations: the socialist econ-
omic sector in industry and the small commodity economic
sector in agriculture.
 
Lenin said that the socialist revolution in the country
where the majority of the population consist of small
peasants can be accomplished only by a series of special,
transitional measures which are not necessary at all in
advanced capitalist countries where the hired work-hand
constitutes an overwhelming majority in industry and
agriculture.
 
 
It was necessary to take a series of transitional
measures in our country, too.
 
- As Marxism-Leninism teaches us, after the proletariat
took the power into their own hands, it was necessary for
the socialist transformation of small scale individual
farming to develop industry to some extent which would
supply farm implements, fertilizers, and other technical
means to the countryside, and to enhance the political,
ideological level of the peasants. .
 
Industry in the North, the level of which had been
low, was badly damaged by the Japanese imperialists at
the time of their surrender. There was only a small number
of technical personnel, and raw and other materials were
insufficient. Moreover, the country was. divided inio two
parts owing to the U.S. occupation of South Korea. Accord-
ingly, a certain time was required for an all-round restora-
tion of industry. Besides, many ind:vidual peasants were
at a low level, politically and ideologically.
 
Under these conditions, small commodity economy in
agriculture was destined to hold its leading position for a
considerable length of time.
 
However, this did not mean that our agriculture was
to develop along the capitalist path.
 
 
1
 
 
The tasks at the time confronting the people in the
North were of a transitional character, that is, gradually
go:ng over to socialism by developing the national econ-
emy in a planned manner by relying on large-scale na-
tional:zed industries, while extending and developing the
resulis of democratic reforms. |
 
In order to restra'n the growth of the capitalist sector
in agriculture, the Workers’ Party of Korea took a series of
measures: the acreage of farm land an individual peasant
could own was limited to 5 jungbo; buying and selling,
mortgaging and renting of land were strictly prohibited;
when the owner of land became unable to till it himself, he
must hand it over to the local People’s Committee to be
disir:buted to the peasants with little land.(This land was
equivalent to the state-owned in its nature and called the
“leasehold.’’)
 
These measures, together with the thorough-going
land reform, created very favourable conditions for the
socialist transformation of agriculture.
 
For strengthening the economic relations between
urban and rural districts, the system of tax-in-kind and a
new credit system were introduced and the state-operated
and consumers’ co-op trade network was newly set up and
expanded.
 
Following the democratic reforms, the rehabilitation
and deve:opment of the national economy made rapid
strides. As for agriculture, it shook off its feudal land-
ownership and began to receive positive aid from socialist
industry. As a result, already in 1948, grain output in the
Norih exceeded the pre-war peak by 10.4 per cent. The
North, once a provision-short area, was turned into a zone
with surplus food.
 
From 1946 to 1949, the total agricultural output value
increased by 51 per cent; of which grain increased
by 40 per cent, cotton by 407 per cent, animal products by 85
per cent, silk cocoons by 193 per cent. Our agriculture
cou!d meet basically the demand of urban inhabitants and
industry. In other words, a balance was reached to a cer-
tain extent between industry and agriculture. However, the
mutual relation was not yet closer. This can be explained
 
 
12
 
 
by the fact that our industry was at the stage of rehabili-
tation, and, accordingly, its demand on agriculture was
not so great.(In 1949, of the total industrial and agri-
cultural output value, industry rated at 53.3 per cent.) On
the other hand, agriculture kept relying on the individual
peasants’ small commodity economic sector, backward in
technique.
 
 
Before liberation over 60 per cent of Korea’s total
industrial output was from North Korea, while only 30 per
cent of marketable rice and 20 per cent of marketable
wheat and barley came from North Korea.
 
Though more grain was available for marketing in the
North with the growth of agricultural production after
liberation, its amount was limited. It was inevitable that
the rapidly growing industry would sooner or later find
itself in contradiction with the economic foundation of
individual farming. Moreover, it was self-evident that
long-drawn backwardness in livestock breeding.and in cul-
tivation of industrial crops—the former held five per cent
and the latter two per cent in agricultural produce in the
days of Japanese imperialist rule—would not be easily
eliminated under small commodity economy. What is more,
under the small-scale, scattered individual peasant econo-
my, it would be impossible to improve to a great extent
the peasants’ living and to do away with the source of ex-
ploitation and poverty- once and for all in the countryside.
 
 
Thanks to the land reform, most of the poor peasants
and hired farm hands, who had constituted the overwhelm-
ing majority of the peasant population, became middle
peasants to be the main force in the countryside. How-
ever, there still remained some poor peasants, about 25
per cent of the peasant households, possible object of ex-
ploitation by the rich peasants and profiteers.
 
 
While giving material aid to the poor peasants and
struggling against exploitation, the Workers’ Party of Ko-
rea took steps to establish the state farms and stock farms
and farm-machine hire stations which would play a lead-
ing role in transforming agriculture in socialist way and
 
 
13
 
 
show the broad peasant masses the advantage of large-
scale farming and mechanization of agriculture.
 
During the three-year long war unleashed by the
U.S. imperialists and traitorous Syngman Rheeites, our
agriculture suffered greatly as our industry did. Rural vil-
lages were destroyed or burnt down, over 90,000 jungbo
of farm land was lost and a great number of irrigation
projects and river dikes were destroyed. The number of
draught animals was reduced to about half compared with
the pre-war days. Supply of chemical fertilizers, farm
implements and various kinds of daily necessaries was
sharply cut down.
 
But our agriculture, even under the most difficult con-
dition of war, not only successfully met the demands of
both the front and the rear but advanced steadily towards
socialism.
 
In view of the severe devastation the industrial es-
tablishments suffered in urban districts, the Party con-
centrated its main forces on agriculture. To meet the war
difficulties squarely and restore the agricultural productive
forces, the Party and Government, relying on the aid
given by the peoples of the Soviet Union and other fra-
ternal countries, widely encouraged the joint labour’ or-
ganization such as the ox-share and labour-exchange
teams which had long been practised by the peasants in
our country, while expanding greatly the state farms and
stock farms and the network of farm-machine hire stations.
 
Already in the peaceful construction period before the
war, the Party and Government began to set up state
farms and stock farms by bringing grass and fallow land
under cultivation and on the basis of some livestock
farms and orchards confiscated in accordance with the
Law on Land Reform. However, it was during the war
time that the state farms began to make rapid develop-
ment mainly for the purpose of rapidly restoring the
severely war-damaged livestock breeding and supplying
the front with necessary meat.
 
There were 16 state farms and stock farms including
seven orchards covering an area of some 6,000-7,000
jungbo in the pre-war days. But there were 213 in 1953
 
 
1-4
 
 
with an area of more than 57,000 jungbo, including the
province-run farms and stock farms. They played a great
role for the rehabilitation and development of livestock
breeding and fruit growing, meeting the demands of the
front. Besides, these farms and stock farms newly establish-
ed by rationally utilizing the fallow lands and mountain
slopes provided the war refugees with jobs and made them
settle down.
 
 
It was in the spring of 1950 when the farm machine-
hire stations appeared. By 1953 their number increased
from 5 to 15. The number of tractors increased from 150
to 500 (in terms of 15 h. p.).
 
 
During the war time, the peasants organized on a
wide scale joint labour in various forms.
 
 
In the light of the difficulties created by the shortage
of labour power, draught animals and farm implements, it
was positively encouraged to rationally organize ox-share
and labour-exchange teams on the principle of mutual aid
and co-operation. As a result, from 1951 on, their signifi-
cance and role were further heightened. The entire peas-
ants came to realize through experience more keenly that
without a closer co-operation in labour, successful farm-
ing in the war time was impossible. Consequently, in many
districts, not only in the farm work but also in side-line
production, a new form of cooperative labour, not merely
of temporary, seasonal nature but of the year-round, be-
gan to emerge. And at the end of 1952 the Party and Gov-
ernment decided to organize and develop gradually side-
line co-operatives among the peasanis as one of the mea-
sures for improving the economic situation of poor peas-
ants and fishermen. Moreover, financial and material aid
was given to the newly organized co-operatives, a higher
form than the ox-share and labour-exchange teams.
 
Though the number of the side-line co-ops in the
countryside at that time was not big, some of them went
beyond the livestock breeding and other side-lines, and
began to extend gradually their collective activities to
farming.
 
During the war time, in Kangwon Province, especial-
 
 
15
 
 
ly in the districts near the eastern and central fronts, num-
bers of the front joint work teams were organized.
 
The front joint work teams which were organized
mostly with the young and middie-aged peasants after
their families had been evacuated worked on the land
while aiding the front all they couid. In their initial stage,
it must be pointed out, the front joint work teams had no
rigid rules and reguiations about governing themseives,
but the teams gradually came to assume the spec‘fic fea-
tures of co-operative economy from production to distri-
bution. Membership of the teams ranged from 50 to 200.
The front joint work team represented an embryonic co-
op which emerged when the war was raging in fuil force.
 
By July 1953 when the Armistice Agreement was sign-
ed, they grew into 174 agricultural co-ops (of which 72 were
sideline co-ops) embracing 2,400 peasant househoids.
 
Mention should be made of the fact that all these
socialist forms in the rural economy such as the state
farms and stock farms, farm machine-hire stations and a-
gricultural co-ops in embryo made further deve:opment in the
course of the war, and, overconi?ng difficulties, made a
great contribution to the growth of agricultural produc-
tion in the war time. Grain output in the second year of
the war was greater than in the first year, and that in the
third year bigger than in the second year. Socialist agri-
culture made great contribution to increase grain output
and was a positive factor in promoting the socialist trans-
formation of agriculture. All these results, as Premier
Kim Il Sung remarked in his “For the Rehabilitation and
Development of the Post-war National Economy,” were at-
tained thanks to the agricultural policy of the Workers’
Party of Korea in the early days of the war for a
gradual conversion of the scattered individual farming in-
to co-operative one while developing the state farms.
 
== Development of Agricultural Co-operative Movement ==
 
=== Objective Requirement for Socialist Transformation of Agriculture and Actual Conditions for the Development of Agricultural Co-operative Movement ===
When the just Fatherland Liberation War against the
armed aggression of the U.S. imperialists and Syngman
Rheeites ended in an historic victory for the Korean people,
the people in the North were confronted with the most
important and difficult task of speedily rehabilitating the
severely devastated national economy and developing it in
order to lay a foundation for a_ self-supporting national
economy and improve rapidly the deteriorated people’s
living conditions.
 
For carrying out this task, the Workers’ Party of
Korea laid out the general line of giving priority to the
development of heavy industry while simultaneously de-
veloping light industry and agriculture. Agricultural co-
opera.ivization was one of the most important prere-
quisites for carry:ng through this general line.
 
 
During the war the material and technical foundation
of agricui:ure had been severely destroyed and there
existed a serious shortage of labour power and draught
animais. It was obvious, thevefore, that so long as the in-
dividual farming remained as it was, it was imposs’b‘e to
hope for the rapid development of agricultural production
and solve the food question, an acute problem that we
faced after the cessation of hostilities. Nor could the priori-
 
 
17
 
 
ty growth of heavy industry and rapid development of
light industry be ensured, nor the development of the na-
tional economy as a whole speeded up. (The gross agricul-
tural output value in 1953 decreased to 76 per cent com-
pared with the pre-war year of 1949, of which grain drop-
ped io 88 per cent, vegetables to 58 per cent, cotton to
23 per ceni, fruits to 72 per cent and-silk cocoon to 58
per cent.)
 
 
In the post-war period, with the enormous aid from
the Soviet Union and other fraternal countries, our indus-
tries have been rapidly reconstructed, far bigger in their
scope than before, and equipped with up-to-date machines.
 
 
Under these circumstances, agriculture had to keep
pace with the qualitative changes taking place in the field
of industry.
 
 
On the contradiction between industry and agriculture
which was becoming acute in the post-war days, Comrade
Kim Il Sung pointed out as follows: “Thus the contradic-
tion between the socialist industry and the individual
peasant economy was pregnant with the danger of creat-
ing a grave disproportion between the rapidly recovering;
developing and qualitatively changing industry and the
rural economy which was. being rehabilitated at a snail’s
pace in the postwar situation prevailing in our country.”
(On the Victory of Socialist Agricultural Co-operativization and
Further Development of Agriculture in Our Country)
 
 
Under the condition in which the peasants’ living had
deteriorated to the exireme and the individual farming
existed, it was impossible to solve the question of poor
peasanis, the most acttie one in the postwar days, and to
do away with the source of exploitation. During the war
our agriculture was further deteriorated and the number of
poor peasants increased to about 40 per cenit of the total
peasants. In this situation, agricultural co-operativization
was the only way out of predicament for our peasants.
With agriculiural co-operativization alone, it was possible
to overcome the lack of labour power, draught animals and
 
 
18
 
 
farm implements and all other difficulties, and ensure the
rapid rehabilitation and development of agricultural pro-
ductive forces and enhancement of the peasants’ living
standards.
 
Unless agriculture had been placed under a socialist
system, it would have been imposs‘bie to successfully re-
model enterprisers, tradesmen, and handicrafismen in ur-
ban districts, who, though they were small in number, were
closely related with individual peasants. (In 1953, the
private capitalist and small commodity economic sectors
held 3.9 per cent in the gross industrial output value, and
32.5 per cent in the value of retail trade.)
 
Agricultural co-operativization was, therefore, a law-
governed requirement for social, economic development in
the transitional period.
 
The 6th Plenum of the Central Committee of the
Workers’ Party of Korea held in August 1953, laying down
the basic line for the post-war national economic recon-
struction and development, put forth the historic task of
agricultural co-operativization.
 
 
However, it must be pointed out that the agricultural
co-operativization movement was launched under very
unfavourable conditions, that is, the war damage was
great, the country remained split, and there was hardly
any farm machines to speak of.
 
In this difficult period, the Party took the policy of
agricultural co-operativization. It was a most timely poli-
cy. Should such policy not have been taken after the war
because our revolution was at the stage of anti-imperial-
ist, anti-feudal democratic revoluiion so far as the whoi:e
of Korea was concerned and because we lacked heavy in-
dustry to provide agriculture with modern machines, it is
quite obvious what the results would have been.
 
To be sure, there were some who coniended that agri-
cultural co-operativization was premature. They used to say:
“Our country still remains split,’ “We have no farm ma-
chines,” and so forth.
 
First of all, they did not fully understand what the lawful
objective requirement had arisen inthe course of the devel-
 
 
19
 
 
opment of the national economy in the northern part of
the country, and that unless the democratic base in the
North, the source of our revolution, was strengthened poli-
tically, economically and culturally, the country’s unifica-
tion is quite imposs’ble.
 
Socialist construction in the North, including agricul-
tural co-operativization, is an inevitable requirement aris-
ing in the course of the social and economic development
in the North.
 
South Korea has not been liberated yet, but we can-
not stop a forward movement in the North and wait for
the liberation of South Korea. Nothing can hold back the
revolution and social, economic development in the North.
Only by strengthening further the democratic base in the
North by carrying out socialist construction, can the coun-
try’s peaceful unification be accelerated.
 
Second, they did not understand fully our peculiar con-
ditions of land and agricultural production. Without co-
operativization, the introduction of mechanization and ad-
vanced technique would be impossibie in our couniry.
 
Such dogmatic, formulistic views were severely cri-
tisized in time by the Party.
 
This should not be taken, however, to mean that the
division of the country and the technically low level of
agriculture presented no adverse condition to the agricul-
tural co-operativization. To a certain extent they did. But
they were not fatal factors which could make the agricul-
tural co-operativization imposs’ble.
 
In launching the agricultural co-operative movement
in the North, the Party took account of the necessity and
matured conditions for the movement.
 
Premier Kim I] Sung said, “The agricultural co-opera-
tive movement is a reflection of matured conditions at the
present stage of the development of ihe country and the
lawful, objective requirement of social development.”
(For the Rehabilitation and Development of the Post-war Na-
tional Economy, Korean Ed., p. 346)
 
There were favourable conditions for agricultural co-
operative movement: the people’s democratic power was
established in the country; the socialist industry was
 
 
20
 
 
playing the leading role in the national economy; and the
land reform and other democratic reforms had been
thoroughly carried out and especially the worker-peasant
alliance strengthened through the ordeal of the Fatherland
Liberation War. Moreover, since the peaceful construction
period before the war, such socialist form of economy as
the state farms and stock farms, farm machine-hire sta-
tions, consumers’ co-ops, peasants’ banks, etc. had come
into being in the countryside. Then there were such po-
pular joint work teams as the ox-share and labour-ex-
change teams, which had a long standing in the country-
side, from which the co-operative economy began to
emerge, Furthermore, the enormous material and technical
aid given by the Soviet Union and other fraternal coun-
tries enabled us to use their rich experiences of agricul-
tural co-operative movement to good advantage.
 
Marxism-Leninism teaches us that under the small
peasant economy, ‘as a rule, it is impossible to fully intro-
duce modern farm machines and up-to-date technique.
 
So long as the land owned by peasants was too small
and the individual peasant economy prevailed, the introduc-
tion of machines and advanced farming method was
hampered. Had we waited the comp:etion of mech-
anization before we started co-operativization, it would
have brought about a stagnation in agriculture and
eventually bankrupicy.
 
Therefore, the agricultural co-operativization could not
be postponed until the completion of industrialization and
mechanization.
 
To be sure, industrialization would provide favoura-
ble conditions for agricultural co-operat:vization. How-
ever, when we take into account the peculiar conditions of
our country, it was the only correct and practical way to
effect agricu!tural co-operativization in conform¢ty wih the
matured objective requirement, create favourab.e conditions
for mechanization of agriculture and then acceierate soci-
alist industrialization.
 
As everyone knows, co-operative labour, no matter
how simple it may be, is far superior to scattered, indivi-
dual labour. Marx pointed out in the Capital as follows:
 
 
Zl
 
 
‘Not only have we here an increase in the productive
power of the individual, by means of co-operation, but the
creation of a new power, namely, the coliective power .of
masses.” And it was Lenin who said that the transition
from individual peasant economy to joint economy will
raise labour productivity 2-3-fold and save 2-3-fold in
man-power,
 
In the post-war days it was urgent to rapidly restore
and develop agriculture. To cope with the situation our
peasants had to take the advantage of co-operative labour.
Taking this actual situation into full consideration, our
Party put forth the task of carrying out agricultural co-
operativization prior to industrialization, However, this
should not be taken to mean that technical revolution was
neglected in completing socialist transformation of agricul-
ture. The Party, putting forth the task of agricultural co-
operativization, paid special attention to the development of
heavy industry for technical reform in all branches of the
national economy including agriculture. At ihe same time
it was expected to receive up-to-date farm machines from
the Soviet Union and other socialist countries.
 
=== Party’s Policy on Agricultural Co-operativization and Its Successful Implementation ===
Embarking upon the road of co-operativization, the
Party had to direct serious consideration to the following
special circumstances. Peasants had little experiences in
organizing and running the co-ops, their cultural and tech-
nical standards were low, and the private ownership of
land was still in effect.
 
Consequently, the Workers’ Party of Korea took the
road of organizing several co-operatives in each county
while preserving the private ownership of land and other
means of production. And as experiences were accumulat-
ed, co-ops were organized on an extensive scale.
 
It must be pointed out that the Party, in guiding the
 
 
22
 
 
co-operative movement, paid profound concern towards
the attitude of all strata of peasants.
 
The basic class policy of the Party in rural] areas was
to rely firmly on the poor peasants, strengthen the alliance
with the middle peasants, and to restrict and remould the
rich peasants. At the time when the co-operative movement
was started, the stratum of peasants was divided into poor
and middle peasanis, its ratio being roughly 40:60. During
the war, the rich peasants dropped from 2-3 per cent to 0.6.
Most of the middle peasants were those who came into
being after the land reform.
 
Poor peasants who realized the importance of joining
the co-ops came out most strongly supporting the co-
operativization, and most of the middle peasanis, too,
readily approved co-operativization from the start. How-
ever, there were some middle peasants who, wavering and
hesitating, sat on the fence, while the rich peasants were
indifferent or hostile to the policy.
 
To those wavering middle peasants the Party used
the means of explanation and persuasion, letting them
see everything with their own eyes. Towards the rich
peasants, the Party strictly prohibited the practice of ex-
ploitation, but kept the door open for those who sincerely
wanted to work as socialist working people. The Party
took necessary steps to take sanctions against the small
number of rich peasants who were trying to undermine the
co-operative movement,
 
Lenin’s program for agricultural co-operatives and
the historic experience of the Soviet Union showed
that it was of importance for developing the co-operative
movement to correctly define the forms of co-operative
economy on the principle of combining the individual
interests with the common interests in accordance with the
development of agricultural productive forces.
 
Hence, our Party, taking into consideration the ex-
periences in the People’s Democracies and turning to ac-
count the forms of ox-share teams and _ labour-exchange
teams, formulated the three forms of agricultural co-
operative in accordance with different extent of prepared-
ness and economic status of peasants,
 
 
23
 
 
The first form was the permanent mutual-aid team. In
this case work is done jointly but the land is individually
owned. This is an embryonic socialist form.
 
The second form was the semi-socialist form. In this
case the land is pooled for common economy and over
80 per cent of incomes are distributed to the members ac-
cording to the number of work-days and 20 per cent ac-
cording to the size of land contributed.
 
The third form is a complete socialist form. In this
case the land is turned into co-op ownership and incomes
distributed only according to work done.
 
 
The draft animals and farm implements were not
turned into co-operative ownership automatically. It was
according to the wish of the owner whether they belonged
to the co-ops or remained in private ownership, However,
draft animals and farm implements were used for muiual
benefit and duly paid if they were turned into co-operative
ownership.
 
 
The three forms of agricultural co-operative and the
method of pooling the means of production clearly reflect
the policy of our Party on completing the co-operativiza-
tion by firmly relying on the poor peasants and consoli-
dating the alliance with the middle peasanis.
 
 
At the initial stage of the co-operativization, our
Party adhered to the principle of the gradual development
of co-ops both in form and size, “from an elementary form
to an advanced one and from a small scale one to a large
scale one.” But rejecting a mechanical interpretation of
the principle, the Party instructed that if the level of the
consciousness of the peasants was high and managerial
personnel were well prepared, it was possib:e and neces-
sary to form from the beginning a co-op of the advanced
form on a comparatively big scale.
 
In organizing agricuitural co-operatives, the Party
adhered strictly to the Leninist principies, white tak ng
every precaution against wrong tendencies. Some co-ops
were only interested in the rapid quantitative growth and
advanced forms of co-operative in contravention of the
voluntary principle and mutual benefits. Then there were
 
 
24
 
 
some who took such attitude that; the co-operative move-
ment should take iis natural course, not comprehending
the growing demand of the peasant masses. It was of
tremendous significance for the future development of the
co-operative movement that co-ops were organized with
the poor peasants and the most active e'ements in each
locality, and that the Party and Government concentrated
their leading forces on making these first co-ops register
a great success in production, thereby demonstrating by
examples the advantage of the co-operative economy to the
broad masses of peasants.
 
The per unit area yield of grain of over 1,000 co-ops
organized on ‘an experimental basis during the period
1953-54, was 10-50 per cent higher than that of individual
farming, and their cash ‘incomes 2-7 times bigger.
 
The agro-stock and agro-fishing co-ops organized in
mountainous and coastal areas where poor peasants made
up a greater proportion also registered a great success,
adhering to the slogan of the Party: “Make the best use
of the mountains and the seal”
 
Though such excellent results were achieved by the
co-ops at the experimental stage, some deviations and
shortcomings cropped up. Some leading personnel in agri-
culture revealed impetuous tendencies, while others took a
passive attitude towards the creative zeal of peasants for
organizing co-ops. Then there were some who, on the plea
of strict adherence to voluntary principle, chose to sit
down and wait for the organization of co-ops to take place
spontaneously.
 
In some villages, where there had been already two
or three co-ops organized, some contended that no more
co-ops were needed.. Even there were some cases where
the newly organized co-ops were refused reg'stration for
several monichs.
 
Such conservative tendency was also revealed in de-
ciding ihe form and size of co-ops. In some rural areas,
sticking to the “principte” of distributing shares according
to the land invested, some leading personnel demanded
that the third form of co-op which the peasants had set up at
their own will be reorganized into a second form. And
 
 
25
 
 
there were some who maintained that the membership of
a co-op should not exceed 20 to 30 households.
 
Such conservative tendencies at the experimental
stage were not without reason.
 
Some.imes the policy of organizing several co-ops in
each county on an experimental basis was mechanically
interpreted. Then there were some cases when the lead-
ing personnel lacked a deep understanding of the inner
life of the new co-op. They fell short of experience and
knowledge necessary for guiding the co-ops.
 
Undesirabie tendencies, however, were not limited to
the leading personnel. In one or another shape, they were
also found among peasants. Illustrative of this was their
failure to observe the principle of mutual benefits.
 
 
Excess was to be noted in turning or not turning the
land, draft animals and means of produciion into co-
operative ownership in accordance with the rules. When
the privately-owned preperty was placed under co-opera-
tive ownership, there were cases when correct evaluation
and compensation were not duly made.
 
Also shortcomings were found in management, Some
co-ops, without careful consideration of their economic
foundation, invested a large sum of fixed capital in build-
ing facilities beyond their power or bought large-size
farm machines, and wasted money and materials for non-
productive purposes. There were cases when the co-ops
attempted to run too big a factory or go into trade on the
pretext of running a side-line business.
 
There were many more cases of this nature differing
only in degree: violation of the principle of democracy in
management, lack of planning in the organization of pro-
duction and labour, levelling in calculating workdays and
distributing shares, improper control of common pro-
perties, utter negiect or excessive accumulation of joint
funds, etc.
 
Our co-ops have come to see, through their own ex-
periences, and thanks to the guidance and assistance of
the Party and government organs, what harmful con-
sequences would be entailed by those shortcomings and
 
 
26
 
 
defects, and worked out proper measures to correct such
shortcomings and defects. Neediess to say, root:ng tien
Ou: wds a major question to be dealt with. Experience in
the first year of co-ops proved valuable for the further de-
velopment of co-operativization. On the basis of the tre-
mendous achievements scored at the experimental siage,
the co-operative movement developed on a mass scale
from 1955, with the mass influx of middle peasants, the
main body of the rural population, besides poor peasants.
Co-operatives embraced 1.2 per cent of peasant households
at the end of 1953 to 31.8 per cent at the end of 1954, then
to 44.7 per cent in the spring of 1955.
 
With the rapid development of the co-operative move-
ment on a mass scale, many deviations and negative
phenomena cropped up in the organizational work. The
major deviations were to be seen in the hasty “leftist”
tendencies in the work of organizing and guiding co-ops.
In some places, the organizational work was done not in-
frequently in an administrative manner or in a “hot-and-
cold” fashion on the pretext of overtaking and surpassing
other districts.
 
Some leading personnel organized recklessly some
large-scale co-ops on the ground that it would tend to
“simplify” the guidance work, underestimating the lower
forms of co-op or encroaching upon the inierests of indivi-
dual peasanis on the plea of co-operative’s interest.
 
Negative phenomena also appeared among the peas-
ants themselves, reflecting the frame of mind of the middle
peasants; some peasanis with comparatively stable econo-
mic foundations organized co-ops exclusively among
themselves refusing admittance of poor peasanis; the
acreage of kitchen gardens was expanded in violation of
the rules, some able-bodied members of a family were re-
fused to join the co-op. And they tried to raise the evalua-
tion beyond market prices of draught animals, farm im-
plemenis and others which they coniributed to the co-op.
 
There were even cases when some hostile elements
taking advantage of the mass organization of co-ops,
wormed iheir way into them to occupy leading positions
under the guise of active peasants.
 
 
27
 
 
For the purpose of rapidly making riddance of the
above-mentioned deviations and negative phenomena
manifested in the organization of co-ops. and ensuring a
steady development of the entire co-ops, our Party put
forward its basic line of ensuring both the numerical
growth and qualitative consolidation of co-ops and com-
pleting socialist transformation of agriculture. As the co-
operative movement entered the new phase of mass devel-
opment, the most urgent question was consolidation of the
co-ops organizationally and economically.
 
 
It was of prime importance for the qualitative consoli-
dation and steady development of co-ops to solve the
question of cadres, including the chairmen. The cadre pro-
blem became further complicated due to the fact that many
rural Party members and cadres trained and brought up
during post-liberation period were killed during the war.
 
 
Considering the source of managerial personnel
should be found among the co-op members, our Party ap-
pointed as managerial cadres active members who enjoyed
the confidence of peasants and who had rich experiences
in farmirig, and particularly, the beleft families of patriotic
martyrs, servicemen’s families, and ex-servicemen, Also,
special concern was paid to training and reeducating
them at the central or provincial co-op managerial cadres’
schools, and raising the level of their business ability
through short courses and experience-swapping meetings.
 
 
At the same time, to make the managerial cadres be-
come true servants of the people, to establish the mass
style of work and to bring their work closer to production,
the desk work was simplified so that the cadres could partici-
pate in production.
 
Historic experience in the agricultural co-operativiza-
tion in the Soviet Union showed that success or failure of
a collective farm depends on who stands in the van and
leads the work of the collective farm. Therefore, our Party
directed the main force of the Party and Government to
the guidance work to young co-ops. Social?st order and
system were to be established in the rapidly growing co-
ops, production to be increased gradually, the life of mein-
 
 
28
 
 
bers to be improved and the Party’s position in rural
areas to be consolidated further.
 
To this end, the principte of correctly combining the
day-to-day guidance with the intensive guidance was ad-
hered to, and the central guidance with the local gui-
dance.
 
However, in the early period of the co-operative move-
ment, the guidance work could not keep pace with the
rapid changes taking place in the countryside.
 
Under these circumstances, the Party rendered every
assistance to the leading workers to correctly understand
the inner life of the co-operative and acquire relevant eco-
nomic and technical knowledge. And this helped greatly
the local Party and government organs to give better
guidance to the co-ops. Yet, it was far from removing the
discrepancy between the rapid quantitative growth of the
co-ops and their qualitative changes.
 
The most effective method of solving this question
was intensive guidance, which the Party conducted on a
nation-wide scale once or twice a year by mobilizing thou-
sands of leading workers of Pyongyang and local dis-
tricts. |
 
In this way, the Party succeeded in exposing and
correcting negative phenomena, Any distortion of the co-
operativization policy was corrected, abie managerial
cadres were selected and allocated, democratic princ‘ples
were put into practice fully in the co-ops, socialist labour
discipline and the rational system of distributing shares
were firmly established, the planned development of co-
ops was enforced, and the members’ socialist ideology and
consciousness were enhanced. At the same time, through
this guidance work, the managerial staff of the co-ops
raised the level of political and managerial work. And the
Party and government workers who were mobilized for
this work acquainted themselves fully with the inner life
of the co-operative, enabling them to become more com-
petent in the guidance work. |
 
The struggie for implementing the decis'on of the
December 1956 Plenum of the Party Central Committee,
which is of historic significance in the post-war socialist
 
 
29
 
 
construction, brought about also an epoch-making change
in the field of guidance of co-ops. The Party d:spatched
Presidium members of the Party Ceniral Committee and
other Party and government leaders to co-ops. They dis-
cussed with ihe co-op members the successful fulfilment of
the arduous tasks of the First Five-Year Plan (1957-1961),
learn'ng what difficulties and other urgent questions the
co-op members faced and what would be the best way to
overcome the difficulties and solve the questions. This
served as an important factor in bringing about the epoch-
making upsurge in agricultural production. Bureaucratic,
formalistic leadership and conservatism formerly observed
in the field of guidance of the rural economy were shatier-
ed to pieces and the creativeness and inventiveness of the
masses of the co-op members were stimulated greaily.
 
Proceeding from the principle that the main task of
co-ops is to raise the yield of agricultural produce and
members’ incomes by organizing economic activities cor-
rectly, greater concern has been paid to the reasonable
utilization of natural conditions including land and the
constant growth of labour productivity. Under the cir-
cumstances in which each co-op member owned no more
than 0.9 jungbo of land on an average, they should turn
the co-operative economy into the best use. Every poss:bie
help and guidance was given to raise per unit area yield by
adopting the principle of planting proper crop on proper
soil, raising the land utility rate and introducing widely
various advanced intensive farming, and at the same time
to develop in a diversified and planned way farming, live-
stock farming, sericulture, fruit growing and fishery under
the naiural and economic conditions of the locality.
 
In order to st'mulate enthusiasm for greater produc-
tion and material interests of co-op members measures
were taken for reorganizing the emulation drive of the
past, i.e. under individual economy to meet the new situa-
tion. Moreover, a wide-scale movement was started for
establishing model agricultural co-operatives. A new sys-
tem was established; when work teams and sub-teams
overfulfilled production assignments, those teams were to
be awarded in kind and cash. Contrary to this, when they
 
 
30
 
 
did not fulfil their plans, a certain number of workdays
were deducted.
 
 
In order to relieve the women members, whose num-
ber was more than half of the co-op membership, from
their everyday household chores, more day-nurseries,
kindergariens, laundries, d-ess-making shops and other
public service establishments were built. All this greatly
improved the working conditions for the women members.
And it must be added that these measures which had not
been seen at the experimental stage showed a new develop-
ment in the co-operative movement.
 
 
Particular attention was paid to keeping the balance
between accumulation and expenditure of the co-ops with
a view to consistently carrying out the extended reproduc-
tion and guaranteeing the systematic enhancement of the
living standards of co-op members.
 
Proceeding from the principle that, until co-op mem-
bers completely recover from war damages, first conside-
ration should be given to the improvement of co-op mem-
bers’ life and the consolidation of their econom’c founda-
tion, the rate of reserve funds was limited below 5 per cent
of incomes while greater shares were divided among co-op
members.
 
 
Lenin stressed that every social system arises only
with the financial] assistance of a definite class and ihe sys-
tem which the socialist state must assist more than
the usual is the cooperative system.
 
 
This theme of Lenin was of particular importance in
the realities of our country where agricultural co-ops were
organized and developed on the war ruins.
 
Under the guidance of our Party, the state investment
in the rural economy increased steadily.
 
 
Altogether 120 million won was invested by the state
in the fieid of rural economy between 1954 and 1958.
Irrigation projects and river dykes were built, the net-
work of machine-hire stations was extended and technical
personnel in this field were trained in large numbers. In
addition, the state appropriated enormous funds to re-
 
 
31
 
 
habilitate or construct chemical fertilizer factories and
farm implements factories.
 
This made it poss’ble to lay and consolidate success-
fully the material and technical foundation of the severely
ruined rural economy in a short period after the war.
 
Besides, the state loaned over 300,000 tons of provi-
sions and seed grains, and more than 243 million won of
farming fund to economically weak co-ops and poor peas-
ants. Moreover the state cancelled more than 160,000 tons
of tax-in-kind and loaned grains and more than 14 million
won of loan.
 
 
In 1956 a system of paying fixed amount of tax-in-
kind was enforced throughout the country to lighten the
burden of the peasants and raise their interests in produc-
tion, reducing markedly the rate of tax-in-kind. Measures
were also taken to reduce another 5 per cent of the amount
of tax-in-kind in co-ops and considerably increase the
purchasing price of agricultural produce,
 
 
In the post-war period the Parity and. government
bodies sent tens of thousands of ex-servicemen and many
junior and senior middie school graduates to the coun-
tryside to relieve the acute labour shortage,
 
Moreover, every year in farming seasons numerous
office employees, students and servicemen were mobilized
to help with farming. Every year millions of workdays
were given to the countryside.
 
 
All the successes won by our agricultural co-operati-
ves in overcoming hardships and difficulties in the early
post-war period cannot be imagined apart from the con-
cern shown by the state.
 
The state has always given special favour to agricul-
tural co-ops and at the same time has shown careful con-
cern for individual peasants, too.
 
Along with the development of co-operative economy,
measuves were taken to correct in time even the slightest
tendencies to underestimate individual peasant economy.
And co-ops gave private peasanis every  possib‘e
assistance, materially and technically. This greatly
conduced to bringing individual peasants into the co-ops.
 
 
32
 
 
From ithe experiences gained in the process of or-
ganizing agricultural co-ops we have learned the following
facts:
 
Firstly, the level of political and ideological con-
sciousness of co-op members and the sbservance of prin-
ciple of voluntariness in organizational work exerted
decisive influence on the work of co-ops. Agricultural co-
ops organized with politically and ideologically prepared
persons on the principle of strict voluntariness achieved
successes from the early days of organization and deve-
Icped rapidly. On the other hand, some co-ops. organ-
ized in violation of these principles failed to set up
discipline and order, their production was also meagre
and unity of ideology and will among co-op members was
lacking. There were even a few isolated cases of members
leaving the co-ops.
 
Secondly, abiliiy and responsibility of the managerial
personnel of co-ops and iheir popularity among the masses
constituted decisive factors for the development of co-ops.
The co-ops run by able and responsible cadres achieved
great successes in production. In such co-ops, discipline
and order were well established and things moved along
in a planned manner. However, some co-ops run by in-
compeient cadres gained nothing but negative results.
 
Thirdly, it is importani to take into consideration the
preparedness of co-op members, and the ability of the
ménagerial cadres in particular, in deciding the size of
co-ops. The too big co-ops organized in the early days and
those which had been expanded into too big ones after their
formation made progress at a snail’s pace because of in-
ability of the managerial cadres and irrational organization
of labour. Subsequently measures were taken for dividing
too large co-ops into smaller ones and for merging too
small co-ops inio larger ones, based strictly upon the
voluntary will of the co-op members. Special attention was
paid to the merger of small co-ops in particular. The co-
ops which were unable to develop further because they were
so small in size, or those co-ops in which rational farming
was impossible because their land and irrigation facilities
were interlocked, were merged, The premature merger at
 
 
a3
 
 
the managerial personnel’s judgment was strictly prohibited.
 
Fourthly, the enemy within the co-ops is more dan-
gerous than those without.
 
Fifthly, it was revealed that the organizational, political
activities of the Party organizations and the role of the
Party members in co-ops were of great significance for
strengthening the co-ops.
 
Sixthly, the co-ops in which the local Party organiza-
tions and Government organs had promptly corrected
defects made rapid development. But those which were
otherwise remained in a backward state.
 
From the experiences accumulated in the management
of the co-ops we have learned the following facts:
 
First. Most important in consolidating and developing
agricultural co-ops organizationally and economically is
ensuring democracy in every way. In such co-ops where
the members, as the masters of the co-ops, had taken part
positively in the work of the co-ops and democracy had
been ensured, everything went along without a hitch re-
sulting in a rapid development of co-ops. On the other
hand, there was a small number of co-ops where democracy
had not been ensured. In such cases the co-ops lagged
behind.
 
Second. Great difference was to be noted in harvest
and income between the co-ops that set up the production
plans in conformity with the natural, economic conditions
and organized efficiently the work, and the co-ops which did
the contrary.
 
Third. Rational organization of labour, strict labour
discipline, the correct calculation and assessment of work-
days and rigid observance of socialist remuneration system
constituted key factors for the development of co-ops, In
such co-ops where all this had been well observed labour
enthusiasm of the co-op members reached a high level,
labour productivity was stepped up and eventually all the
work carried out in time. But, in the co-ops where no such
principles were observed the results were very negligible.
 
Lastly, if the co-ops reaped better harvests and raised
incomes compared: with the time when the members had
been individual farmers, and compared with the neighbour-
 
 
Jd
 
 
ing individual peasants they produced a good effect on
them. It promoted the desire of the individual peasants to
join the co-ops, while strengthening the unity of the co-op
members. On the contrary, such co-ops, though small in
number, which failed to raise their harvest and incomes
had a bad effect on the neighbouring individual peasants.
 
At the stage of mass development of agricultural co-
operative movement, more valuable, abundant experiences
were accumulated than at the experimental stage, which
constituted a sure guarantee for the further development
of the agricultural co-operative movement.
 
The Third Congress of the Workers’ Party of Korea
convened in April 1956 set forth the task of bringing the
agricultural co-operative movement to a successful con-
clusion. It was at such a time when socialism was taking
the offensive in all branches of the national economy.
 
 
In order to complete agricultural co-operativization at
the earliest possible date, our Party was greatly concerned
about the rich peasants who remained outside of co-ops,
while concentrating guidance on such districts where the
rate of co-operativization was low.
 
 
As of June 1956, while about 80 per cent of the total
peasant households were embraced in co-ops in North and
South Pyongan and South Hamkyung Provinces, the rate
of co-operativization was 56 per cent in Jagang Province,
a mountainous district where the villages are scattered
and geographical conditions are unfavourable, 44 per cent
in the neighbourhood of Pyongyang where the peasants
were interested in trading and 42 per cent in Kaesong and
its neighbourhood, newly liberated area. Some peculiarities
were to be noted in Kaesong and its neighbouring villages.
The area had not been so long under the people’s democra-
tic system, for they had been liberated not long ago and
had some peculiarity in landownership and other aspects.
 
In view of such situation, the Party had to carry out
the organizationa] work in the mountainous areas, city
suburbs, and newly liberated areas. The problem of rich
peasants who still remained outside the co-operatives had
to be solved.
 
 
35
 
 
In mountainous areas, measures were taken to
organize small-scale independent combined work teams
taking into account the fact that the people were living
scattered and to set up joint livestock farms to bring
together the peasants who lived far apart from each other.
 
In the rural villages adjacent to towns, where the
affairs of individual peasants were closely linked with
private traders, agricultural co-operativization was carried
out in parallel with the socialist transformation of the ‘in-
dividual traders and enterprisers.
 
 
Taking into consideration the fact that in the newly
liberated area the political and cultural level of peasants
was generally low while the desire for the private land
ownership was comparably sirong, the Party concentrated
efforts on penetrating the policies of the Party and
Government among them. In particular, efforts were
directed to smashing the intrigues designed by such anti-
Party and anii-revolutionary elements as the overthrown
landed gentry, capitalists and pro-Japanese elements, and
Wiping out the evil consequences therefrom, while streng-
thening the work of bringing up the nucleus members.
Moreover, the Party helped the co-operative members
choose a form of co-operatives which is most suitable to
their aciual situation.
 
 
As for the rich peasants, as already mentioned above,
the Party observed the principle of remoulding them by
peaceful means, instead of liquidation by the method of
confiscation. This was possible because the socialist re-
volutionary forces were strong, whereas the position of rich
peasants was insignificant.
 
 
Along wiih the individual industrialists and traders
in cities and towns, most of rich peasants came to realize
through the practical experiences in the revolutionary and
historical development in our country that the only way out
was to become socialist working people. Never relaxing
the education of the rich peasants, the Party concentrat-
ed main efforts on consolidating the already organized co-
operatives organizationally and economically, proceeding
from the principle that “if the co-operatives are strength-
 
 
aft
 
 
ened and their members’ life is better than that of the in-
dividual peasants, they will join the co-operatives of their
own accord.” (From the speech delivered by Premier
Kim Il Sung at the Meeting of Managerial Workers of Co-
operatives in South Pyongan Province.) At the same time,
the Party attached great importance to the co-operatives
of low forms.
 
 
With the strengthening of the economic foundation
of agricultural co-operatives as a whole and the collapse of
the last foothold for exploitation in the countryside, the
most stubborn rich peasants came willingly and volun-
tarily into the co-operatives.
 
 
It confirmed once more the correciness of the Party
policy on transforming rich peasants by peaceful means.
 
 
However, this is not to say that the socialist trans-
formation in the countryside was carried out without a
class struggle. On the contrary, it accompanied a severe
class struggle. The overthrown exploiting classes did not
give up the wild fancy of restoring the old system and the
American imperialists nesting in South Korea and, their
puppet, the Syngman Rhee clique were in a frenzy to carry
out subversive activities against the northern part of our
Republic. The class enemies resorted to every vile scheme
to disintegrate the agricultural co-operatives from within
and without: reactionary rumours vilifying the Party poli-
cy on the agricultural co-operativization were spread, the
joint properties of the co-ops were the targets of their
production plans, and even attempts were made on co-op
cadres’ lives.
 
 
Particular mention should be made of the fact that as
the agricultural co-operativization was nearing completion
and the victory of socialism was fortified in cities and the
countryside, the machinations, sabotages and subversive
activities of the counter-revolutionaries who lost their
last foothold became all the more vicious. Consequently,
the Party steadily waged vigorously a mass struggle a-
gainst the counter-revolutionary elements, while strength-
ening the political and ideological work among the peas-
 
 
37
 
 
ants for enhancing their socialist consciousness and re-
volutionary vigilance.
 
In this way, every scheme of the enemy in the rural
areas was exposed and smashed, while safeguarding the
gains of socialism, enhancing the revolutionary spirit and
political enthusiasm of peasants and fortifying them. with
firmer confidence in the ultimate victory.
 
Experiences showed that only by suppressing the
enemy who attempted to restore the old system and_ by
taking appropriate measures against a handful of those
elements who opposed the co-operative movement, could
we promote the all-round development of co-operative
movement and socialist transformation of rich peasants.
 
By the end of August 1958, the tasks laid down at
the Party Third Congress to complete the agricultural co-
operativization by the end of 1961 had been  victoriously
accomplished, And it goes without saying that all this was
possible because of the Party’s correct agricultural co-
operative line and its guidance in conformity with the
concrete reality of our country.
 
The agricultural co-operativization also promoted the
socialist remoulding of private traders and enterprisers in
cities. With the co-operativization of the individua] peasant
economy the capitalist elements in cities lost the last foot-
hold. Thus, in our country the co-operativization of agri-
culture and the socialist transformation of privaie trade
and industry ran parallel and were completed almost at
the same iime. And the fundamental question of the tran-
sitional period, “Who will win?” had been completely solved
in favour of socialism both in cities and rural villages.
 
The agricultural co-operativization was a great revolu-
tion in our countryside. Small-scale individual peasant
economy. based upon the private ownership of the means
of production ihat had existed for thousands of years has
been wiped out once and for all. And our rural communi-
ties have been turned into socialist communities.
 
The completion of agricultural co-operativization made
it possible to solve completely the contradiction existing
between the large-scale socialist industry and small com-
modity individual peasant economy and to ensure the
 
 
38
 
 
balanced development of industry and agriculture. And the
economic relations between town and the countryside have
been further strengthened.
 
In this way, the worker-peasant alliance, the political
basis of our people’s democratic system and the basic
motive power of our revolution, has been further consoli-
dated on a new socialist basis and our Party’s position in
rural areas and revolutionary democratic base in the
northern part further strengthened.
 
=== Major Characteristics of Agricultural Co-operativization ===
The agricultural co-operative movement from the  ex-
perimental stage to the stage of completion in our country
was, first of all, characterised by the rapid speed of develop-
ment. Another characteristic is that an advanced type, the
third form, of agricultural co-ops occupies an absolute
majority.
 
[table]
 
As shown above, the agricultural co-operative move-
ment in Korea maintained an unprecedentedly rapid tempo
and the co-operativization was completed only in 4-5 years.
Moreover, from the first days of the movement, the over-
whelming majority of co-ops were organized in the third
form. In August 1958 all co-ops took the third form. It must
be pointed out that co-ops were organized with little techni-
cal reconstruction of agriculture, but the agricultural co-
operativization was carried out at high speed.
 
 
And then ihe agricultiral co-ops were organized on
the basis of private landownership but the overwhelming
majority of them took the third form from the initial stage
of co-operativization.
 
This fact represents the most important characteristic
of our agricultural co-operativization. All this was possi-
ble, thanks ‘first of all to the high political consciousness
and revolutionary spirit of peasants and because the align-
ment of class forces was decisively favourable for agricul-
tural co-operativization.
 
 
Particularly, it can be explained by the fact that dur-
ing the great Fatherland Liberation War, preliminary con-
ditions were created for the peasants to organize volun-
tarily agricultural co-ops under the guidance of the Work-
ers’ Party of Korea.
 
The Korean peasantry has a revolutionary tradition
of fighting for land and freedom under Japanese imperi-
alist rule. After liberation the peasants were tempered all
the niore through the land reform and the hard trial of the
Fatherland Liberation War.
 
 
In the course of the war they saw more clearly the
barbarity of the U.S. imperialists and the reactionary
nature of the landowner-bourgeois system which the U.S.
imperialists were intending to force upon the Korean peo-
 
le.
" Through the bitter class struggle against the U.S, im-
perialists and Syngman Rhee clique and the resistance of
 
 
An
 
 
the overthrown exploiting class, the toiling peasants were
more closely united around the Party and their revolution-
ary spirit was unprecedentedly heightened. And, fully ap-
preciating the cause of our revolution and the correctness
of the Party’s policy, they had firm confidence that victory
would be always with them if they followed the directives
of the Party.
 
Under the guidance of the working class, the worker-
peasant alliance was further strengthened and the Party’s
position in the rural village consolidated greatly.
 
Though the Party lost many of its core members in
the rural villages during the war, the Party trained a force
of excellent Party members and reinforced Party organi-
zations in every village by bringing up a new core of mem-
bers among peasants. And the Party members in the rural
villages stood in the van of agricultural co-operativization.
 
In the countryside, the revolutionary forces grew
mightier, while the forces of opposition were extremely
weak.
 
As mentioned above, the landowner class was liqui-
dated and the rich peasant economy weakened in the course
of enforcing the land reform. Moreover, the forces hostile
to the agricultural co-operativization were all the more
weakened in the process of the bitter class struggle during
the war time.
 
This fact was one of the important conditions for
accelerating the smooth development of agricultural co-
operative movement.
 
The historical experiences of the great Soviet Union
showed that for the socialist transformation of agriculture,
first of all, the mass movement for collective farms should
be waged among the peasants, and the peasants them-
selves should be convinced of the advantages of collective
farming and take this road of their own accord. To
this end, the work should be carefully done. Of course, for
this a certain length of time was needed.
 
Preliminary conditions for co-operativization in our
country were already matured during the war time. Over-
coming the difficult conditions in which manpower, draught
animals and farm implements were in short, the peasants
 
 
4]
 
 
carried on successfully their farming by strengthening ox-
share and labour-exchange teams. Most of them fully re-
cognized the necessity and superiority of collective work
 
 
The rise of revolutionary spirit and political and ideo-
logical level of the peasants, the steady growth of socialist
sector in the countryside after the liberation, and enhance-
ment of its leading role exerted great influence in helping
the peasants to see the necessity and advantage of collec-
tive work.
 
 
The organization of consumers’ co-operatives embrac-
ing the broad popular masses in the countryside and the es-
tablishment of peasants’ banks gave, to a certain extent,
the peasants co-operative education and training in the field
of commodity circulation and credit. With the expansion
of state farms and stock farms and the machine-hire sta-
tions, the advantages of mechanization of agriculture and
large scale farming were vividly demonstrated.
 
 
The embryonic co-operative economy, which appeared
for the first time during the war time, developed rapidly in
the post-war period. As already mentioned, this fact is
linked with the above-mentioned material and ideological
foundations.
 
 
It should be-also pointed out that at the experimental
stage of co-operativization, the first few agricultural co-
ops organized in every county achieved great successes,
demonstrating the superiority of co-operative economy.
 
 
The successes are linked with the specific features of
landownership created by the land reform and small-scale
farming. After the land reform the Party made it impossi-
ble to turn the land into a means of exploitation or to con-
centrate the land again into the hands of individuals. If a
peasant, who had received land, could not work it, the
Government put this land under the management of the
local People’s Committees. In July 1953, such land totalled
530,000 jungbo, over one fourth of the total arable land.
 
 
Therefore private landownership by toiling peasants
was fundamentally different from the private landowner-
ship of the past.
 
 
42
 
 
It is, in essence, the transitional form of private Iand-
ownership which should gradually and inevitably switch
over to the socialist-collective ownership of the land.
 
The specific features of such landownership had no
small influence on the conception of. the peasants about
landownership.
 
The small and equal size of plots of land owned by
the peasants must also be mentioned here.
 
Even after the land reform, their land was in general
small owing to the fact that the area was limited, the land
was distributed evenly among the peasants in accordance
with the number of work hands and family members.
 
In July 1953 the size of plots of land owned by each
peasant household was as follows: no more than one
jungbo 32.9 per cent of the total peasant households; 1-2
jungbo 41.7 per cent; 2-3 jungbo 19.1 per cent; more than
3 jungbo 6.3 per cent; the average size of land cultivated
by each household throughout the country was no more than
1.8 jungbo.
 
It must be noted that there was very little difference
in the sizes of plots owned by peasants, Each peasant
family owned on the average one jungbo in the paddy-
field area; in the intermountain area, 1.0 jungbo; in the
mountain areas, 2-3 jungbo.
 
The fragmental land owned by no small number of
peasanis made it impossible to raise their living standard.
 
The weak side of individual farming was more vividly
revealed during and after the war.
 
It was quite natural that many peasants actively
joined co-ops in order to extricate themselves from the
posilion of small individual peasant economy.
 
Equality in landownership which minimized the signi-
feance of distribution for the contributed land in the co-
ops and the revolutionary spirit of the peasants provided
important material conditions for organizing the over-
whelming majority of the third form of co-ops in the early
days.
<nowiki>:</nowiki> Tooether with the above-mentioned internal factors it
 
 
no
 
 
should be also pointed out that the enormous economic an
43
 
 
technical assistance of peoples of the Soviet Union and
the other fraternal countries, and the introduction of their
rich and precious experience into our agricultural co-
operativization provided favourable conditions for the de-
velopment of our co-operative movement.
 
 
When they started the socialist co-operativization
the leading workers in the countryside and the peasants
could under the guidance of the Workers’ Party of Korea un-
hesitatingly take the only just direction—the direction
taken by the peoples of the fraternal countries.
 
Correctly calculating on the conditions and factors
for co-operativization which became gradually matured
already in the period of peaceful construction after libera-
tion and during the Fatherland Liberation War, our Party
creatively applied Marxist-Leninist theory on the socialist
transformation of agriculture in accordance with the ob-
jective requirement of social economic development, and
introduced rich experiences of the Soviet Union and the
other fraternal countries in conformity with actual condi-
tions of our country. Thus, the correct line was defined
and timely measures were taken to give every possible
guidance and assistance to agricultural co-operativization.
Therefore, the co-ops in our country were able to develop
at an unprecedentedly rapid pace and to achieve great
successes.
 
 
When the agricultural co-operativization in Korea
forged ahead at a rapid pace and the third form of co-ops
occupied the overwhelming majority, some one hesitated
complaining that “‘the speed of co-operativization was too
rapid and co-operativization trespassed the interests of
the middle peasants.”
 
But the rapid tempo of co-operativization and the
overwhelming majority of the advanced form of co-ops
were completely logical. There is no doubt that unless our
Party had surmounted on time conservatism and passivity
on the basis of the correct appraisal of actual conditions
of the countryside, the task of agricultural co-operativiza-
tion would not have been successfully, like today, com-
pleted in 4 or 5 years after the war. It was shown in the
 
 
44
 
 
process of co-operativization of five years that even under
the condition in which only handicraft technique without
any modern machines and technique is dominant, agricul-
tural co-operativization can be realized and even agricul-
tural co-ops so organized can achieve a decisive superiority
over private peasant economy.
 
It was shown that the landownership and the class-
composition in the rural villages and ihe revolutionary
spirit of the peasants constituted important factors for the
speedy development of the agriculiural co-operative move-
ment. And only with the high degree of enthusiasm of
the peasants to carry out the Party’s correct policy, and the
Party’s and government’s correct leadership and _ help,
agricultural co-ops could be fully consolidated, even though
they rapidly grew in quantity.
 
True, the victory of agriculiural co-operative move-
ment in our country proved vividly the great vitality of the
general principle of Marxism-Leninism on the socialist re-
volution in the countryside and the correctness of agricul-
tural policy of the Party which employed creatively this
principle to our historic conditions.
 
== Sharp Growth of Agricultural Productive Forces and Development of Agricultural Co-op System ==
In the post-war period, our Party directed its great
force to the successfully carrying out of the agricultural co-
operativization and, at the same time, to rapid rebuilding
of the war-devastated material and technical foundation of
agricultural production.
 
On the basis of the priority development of heavy
industry and the advantages of the new relations of pro-
duction established in the countryside, the Party and Gov-
ernment waged the whole-Party and nation-wide struggle
for sharply stepping up agricultural productive forces.
 
 
Having successfully fulfilled the post-war Three-
Year Plan for the Development of the National Economy
(1954-56), our industry witnessed a bigger upsurge from
1957, the first year of the First Five-Year Plan.
 
 
In 1958, the total industrial output value was 4 times
that in the pre-war year of 1949, or 4.3 times that in the
pre-liberation year of 1944.
 
In the five years of the post-war period, the total in-
dustrial output value grew at an average annual rate of
42 per cent, the means of production increased on the
average by 52 per cent annually and consumer goods by
34 per cent, Consequently, an end was put to the severe
colonial onesidedness in industry, and the self-supporting
foundation of the national economy was firmly established.
 
Rapid development of industry served as the most im-
portant guarantee for swiftly rehabilitating and strength-
ening the material and technical foundation of agriculture
 
 
46
 
 
and bringing about a great upsurge in agricultural produc-
tion.
 
During the post-war Three-Year Plan period, our agri-
cultural production topped the pre-war level thanks to the
strugele for carrying out the decisions of the November
1954 and December 1955 plenums of the Central Com-
mittee of the Workers’ Party of Korea. And it continued
to develop rapidly on an extensive scale, bringing about
an unprecedentedly upsurge.
 
In rehabilitating and strengthening the foundation of
agricultural production, the Party attached prime im-
portance to the construction of river dikes and irrigation
systems which were essential for restoring from the damage
caused by natural calamities and for increasing per-unit-
area harvest.
 
57 per cent of the total sum of state investment in
agriculture in the five years of the post-war period was
spent for building river dikes and irrigation systems.
 
Along with the building of the large-scale projects
with state investment, construction of medium- and small-
scale river dikes and irrigation systems was widely un-
dertaken by agricultural co-operatives.
 
During the five years of the post-war period, 629 re-
servoirs and 1,659 pumping stations were reconstructed
or newly built throughout the country. As a result, the
paddy fields under irrigation increased from 227,000 jung-
bo in 1953 to 463,000 jungbo.
 
Especially, the Pyongnam Irrigation System. built
during this period alone supplies water to more than
40,000 jungbo of paddy fields.
 
The proportion of irrigated paddy fields to the total
paddies rose from 52 per cent to 91 per cent during this
period.
 
During the five years of the post-war period, con-
struction of river dikes and breakwaters, anti-erosion pro-
jects and afforestation work were also undertaken exten-
sively to protect over 350,000 jungbo of farmland from the
damage by flood and tidal water.
 
The number of machine-hire stations increased from
 
 
47
 
 
15 to 50, and the number of tractors (in terms of 15 h.p.)
increased fourfold.
 
The Kiyang Farm Machine Factory and many other
farm machine factories were reconstructed or newly built,
and various kinds of efficient farm machines and imple-
ments such as seeders, thrashers and fodder cutters were
supplied in large numbers to the rural villages.
 
The Heungnam Fertilizer Factory and other chemical
fertilizer factories were reconstructed in a short space of
time from severe war-ruins and were expanded. The sup-
ply of chemical fertilizers during the five years since the
war increased 12 times.
 
Agricultural institutes, higher and secondary agricul-
tural schools and courses for training agricultural experts
were built and expanded on a large scale to meet the grow-
ing demands for agro-technicians, while correspondence
courses were opened in higher educational institutes and
technical schools.
 
Under the co-operative economy, it was possible to in-
troduce extensively advanced method of intensive farming
and improve the distribution of crops on the principle of
right crop on right soil.
 
In 1957-58, cold bed seedlings, which signify a tech-
nical innovation in the battle for good rice harvest, were
planted on 50 per cent of the total paddy fields. Introduc-
tion of cold bed seedlings helped increase per-jungbo yield
of rice by 1-1.5 tons compared with ordinary seedlings.
Humus pot planting of cotton, an advanced method which
more than doubles the per-jungbo yield, was applied to
70 per cent of the total area under cotton, The area sown
to maize, a_ high-yielding crop, extended from 236,000
jungbo in 1954 to 826,000 jungbo in 1958, while utility
rate of land rose from 125 per cent to 161 per cent.
 
Owing to these measures and the selfless endeavour
of the peasants, total grain output kept on increasing—
2,870,000 tons in 1956; 3,200,000 tons in 1957; and a re-
cord harvest of 3,700,000 tons in 1958. Grain harvest in
1958 was nearly double that in 1946, shortly after the
liberation. | |
 
 
48
 
 
With the sharp increase of grain output, the food pro-
blem, one of the acute problems in the post-war period, was
solved in the main in 1957. We used to import annually
hundreds of thousands of tons of grain. But today we have
a surplus rice.
 
This is the most brilliant achievement of our socialist
agriculture.
 
The sharp increase of grain output in our country
has resulted primarily from the rise of per-jungbo yield
of farm produce.
 
Extensive introduction of cold bed seedlings, expan-
sion of the irrigated paddy fields, and generous manuring
are the essential conditions for the increase of per-jungbo
yield of grain. In 1956, the average per-jungbo yield of rice
was 24.4 per cent higher than in 1954, and in 1958 it was
32 per cent higher than in 1954. Per-jungbo yield of maize
increased by 30 per cent during the same period.
 
Many advanced agricultural co-operatives have gath-
ered a good harvest inconceivable in the past.
 
Here are a few instances.
 
Dooam Agricultural Co-op, Kangnam County of
South Pyongan Province, gathered on the average 13 tons
of rice per jungbo from 160 jungbo of paddy field in 1958,
and the harvest from 1.5 jungbo of an experimental plot
reached 55 tons.
 
Samryong Agfticultural Co-op, Soonchun County of
South Pyongan Province, harvested an average of 3.6 tons
of maize per jungbo from 422 jungbo of field, and from 12
jungbo of field they reaped 18 tons per jungbo.
 
Wonsa Agricultural Co-op, Ongjin County of South
Hwanghai Province, raised per-jungbo yield of wheat to
4.5 tons.
 
Big achievements have-also been registered in other
branches. The Government has taken a number of mea-
sures for markedly increasing the output of industrial
crops, It has raised state purchasing prices of industrial
crops, preferentially supplied chemical fertilizers and ex-
empted the cotton growers from tax-in-kind.
 
In 1958 per-jungbo yield of cotton doubled that in 1953,
and its total output increased threefold.
 
 
49
 
 
Livestock farming, which suffered most during the
war-time, started making a good headway.
 
By September 1, 1958, the number of cattle in the
country had increased 1.3 times that at the end of 1953,
and that of hogs 2.8 times. Meat output grew 3.2 times
during the five years of the post-war period.
 
Enormous achievements were also. scored in fruit
growing and sericulture.
 
A nation-wide movement is under way for extending
the orchard area by 100,000 jungbo during the First Five-
Year Plan period.
 
More than 50,000 jungbo have been reclaimed for
fruit growing. Total output of fruits in 1958 was 131,000
tons, or 1.8 times as much as the peak harvest in the pre-
war days.
 
In 1958, we produced 8,700 tons of cocoons, or 1.6
times as much as the peak output in the pre-war days.
 
In this way, in the recent years extensive upsurge and
innovation have been registered in grain production and
in all other branches in the countryside where socialism
has triumphed.
 
It must also be noted that, along with the high rate
development of agricultural production, the structure of
agriculture is undergoing change to meet the demands of
the national economy.
 
[table]
 
From the above tables we can see that our agriculture
has taken the course of many-sided development, with
stress on grain. Agricultural production has been stepped
up to supply raw materials to industry and to meet the
growing demands of the population for meat and fruits.
 
Rapid growth of agricultural] production has led to
the strengthening of economic foundation of agricultural
co-operatives and swift improvement of the living of co-
op members.
 
Until 1956 agricultural co-ops set aside on the aver-
age about 5 per cent of their incomes for common reserves.
But, as the living of the co-op members improved steadily,
the rate of common reserve funds increased to about
10 per cent in 1957 and more than 15 per cent in 1958.
 
The total sum of commonly-owned property of our
agricultural co-operatives last year was about 686 million
won, or on the average 51,500 won for each agricultural
co-operative, or on the average 650 won for each co-op
household. Compared with 1955, the sum of commonly-
owned property for each household increased 2.4 times on
the average.
 
This serves to show that our agricultural co-opera-
lives have laid the foundation necessary for steadily ex-
tending reproduction and capital construction,
 
Our agricultural co-operatives have set aside an in-
creasingly greater amount from their incomes and harvest
for common reserve funds, seed, fodder, and grain to be
exchanged with fertilizers. Nevertheless, the share of co-
op members has increased systematically.
 
[table]
 
Shortly after the armistice, poor peasants accounted
for about 40 per cent of the total peasant households. But
in 4-5 years since then their living standards have been
improved to those of middle peasants or above.
 
As the economic foundation of agricultural co-opera-
tives has been consolidated and the living of co-op mem-
bers has improved, construction of modern villages is
undertaken extensively. Our rural villages are changing
their looks with every passing day,
 
Many buildings for common economy such as stalls,
silk-worm breeding rooms and stores, as well as large
numbers of educational, cultural, public health and public
welfare establishments have been built in our countryside.
By the end of 1958, schools with over 8,000 class-rooms,
6,400 nurseries and kindergartens, 9,000 democratic pub-
licity halls and clubs and many clinics, bath houses, bar-
ber shops and laundries were built in the rural areas.
 
Tens of thousands of modern dwelling houses have
been built in the countryside. By the end of 1958, eleciri-
city had found its way to 67 per cent of the rural villages,
one 49 per cent of the peasant households had electric
light.
 
Many agricultural co-operatives have installed tele-
phone service and through-wire radio system.
 
With the enforcement of universal compulsory pri-
mary and middle school education and with the extensive
adult education, cultural standard of peasants has rapidly
improved and new socialist national culture is flowering
in our countryside.
 
Over 50,000 cultural, art and physical culture circles
involving more than one million peasants are now func-
tioning in our rural areas. Ideological consciousness of
peasants is being remoulded.
 
The entire agricultural co-op members, who have
scored great victory following the path shown by the
Party, are firmly determined to further strengthen and de-
velop the co-operative economy and defend to the last the
gains of socialism.
 
The outdated ideological remnants of a smal] property
owner are gradually being eliminated from co-op mem-
 
 
o2
 
 
bers; and with the enhancement of the ideological con-
sciousness of collectivism, unity and solidarity between
co-op members have been further strengthened and our
co-op membérs are taking an active part in joint labour
and are displaying to the full their creative enthusiasm in
socialist construction.
 
All this serves io show that agricultural co-operativi-
zation has brought about a radical change not only in the
relations of production, but also in the cultural and intel-
lectual life of the people.
 
 
The basic line of economic construction of our Party
in the post-war period and the Party’s agricultural policy
are most correct and, to carry out this policy, the entire
peasants under the leadership of the working class have
displayed a high degree of patriotic enthusiasm and
rendered distinguished labour service. Consequenily they
could register such big achievements in agriculture.
 
To strengthen steadily the positive reaction of the
relations of production upon the development of the pro-
ductive forces—this assumes great importance in the
economic policy of the Marxist-Leninist Parties.
 
In this connection Comrade Kim II Sung said:
 
“The socialist co-operative economy system, too,
cannot pause at one place. It must develop and must be
further strengthened.”
 
Since the first day of the agricultural co-operative
movement, our Party has corrected in good time fac-
tors impeding the development of production in the inner
life of agricultural co-operatives, and improved and
strengthened the system and order in agricultural co-
operatives to meet the demands of the steady development
of productive forces.
 
What assumed momentous significance in this con-
nection was the amalgamation of agricultural co-opera-
tives which was carried out throughout the country
between October and November last year.
 
As has already been noted, in guiding the agricultural
co-operative movement our Party has given particularly
prudent atiention to the size of agricultural co-operatives.
 
 
53
 
 
When their size is. too small, agricultural co-opera-
tives will not display to the full the advantages of the
co-operative economy, and, on the contrary, when their
size is too big, agricultural co-operatives will encounter
ereat difficulties in the management of common economy.
 
Here is a table illustrating the growth of the average
size of agricultural co-operatives in our country.
 
 
Average number of Average acreage of
peasant households arable land culti-
embraced inaco-op vated by aco-op
 
[table]
 
The average size of agricultural co-operatives has
grown considerably in 4-5 years, both in the number of
member households and in the acreage of arable land.
 
 
The growth of size of agricultural co-operatives re-
presents the rehabilitation and strengthening of material
and technical foundation of agriculture in the post-war
period—expansion of the network of machine-hire stations
and construction of many irrigation systems—and the
marked enhancement of political and business standards
of the co-op management personnel and the leading per-
sonnel in the field of agricuiture. At the same time,
this corresponded to the rapid development of agricultural
co-operative movement.
 
In the course of mass development of the agricultural
co-operative movement, many peasants joined the already
formed co-ops, while the new co-ops were formed on a
bigger scale than the co-ops formed at the early stage of
 
 
54
 
 
the agricultural co-operative movement. Consequently, the
composition of co-ops in size changed remarkably.
 
[table]
 
By June 1955, co-ops with less than 30 member
households had accounted for the greater part, while in
June 1956 co-ops with member households of 31-50 made
up the greater part, and since March 1957 co-ops with
member households of 51-100 had occupied a greater pro-
portion.
 
At the Conference of Agricultural Co-op Management
Personnel of South Pyongan Province in January 1957,
Comrade Kim Il Sung said that a co-op with 40-100 mem-
ber households was in general a proper size under the
conditions prevailing in our country.
 
A co-op of this size was appropriate at that time, for
it could effectively cultivate its farmland mainly with
handicraft technique, and the co-op could undertake join-
tly certain side-lines.
 
At the experimental stage, the size of agricultural
co-operatives in all districts of the country was almost
 
 
3)
 
 
the same—around 10-20 member households. But a mark-
ed difference was brought about after the co-operative
movement started mass development, Generally speaking,
co-ops in the plain area assumed a bigger size than the
co-ops in the mountain area.
 
This can be explained by the average size of co-ops
in different provinces.
 
[table]
 
In North and South Pyongan Provinces which have
large tracts of plain area, the average number of member
households of a co-op is bigger than in the mountainous
provinces of Jagang and Ryanggang. It is, therefore, self-
evident that the natural-geographical conditions in moun-
tainous districts where peasants lived far apart from each
other and farmland was scattered, constituted the primary
conditions retarding the speed of the development of the
co-operative movement as well as the growth of the size
of co-ops.
 
The comparatively small size proved to be no longer
suited to the rapid progress of agricultural productive for-
ces and to the further development of co-ops. It now be-
came an obstacle to the rational utilization of land,
improvement of labour organization, many-sided develop-
 
 
56
 
 
ment of the common economy and _ especially to the
mechanization of farming. Under the condition of small
scale co-ops, considerable waste and irrationality were
found in the extensive rural construction.
 
Therefore, there arose before our Party the pressing
task of opening up brighter prospects for the development
of agriculture by eliminating the discrepancy between the
comparatively small-scale agricultural co-operatives and
the productive forces and by successfully carrying out the
immediate tasks of technical and cultural revolutions in
the countryside.
 
This was a fully matured task, because the organiza-
tional and economic foundation of agricultural co-ops had
been strengthened and the political and business standards
of co-op management personnel had been raised consider-
ably over the past five years, and because mass produc-
tion of modern equipment and farm machines such as
tractors and lorries started at home.
 
The amalgamation of agricultural co-operatives was
a complicated task. Nevertheless, it was accomplished
smoothly in 1-2 months with the unanimous support of the
peasants.
 
As a result, more than 13,000 agricultural co-ops
were merged into about 3,800, with the average number
of member households of a co-op increasing from 80 to
about 300 and the acreage of the arable land cultivated by
a co-op was extended from 130 jungbo to 500 jungbo.
 
Consequently, agricultural co-operatives were provid-
ed with the conditions for undertaking land construction
on a full scale, more widely introducing modern farm
machines and advanced farming methods, developing the
common economy in a diversified way by making effective
use of natural economic conditions, checking waste of
labour power and materials in rural construction, and for
pushing ahead with the rural construction in a planned
way.
 
How then did the amalgamation of agricultural co-ops
proceed?
 
Agricultural co-operatives were merged into one in
each ri (the lowest administrative unit), and the chairman
 
 
57
 
 
of the ri people’s committee is appointed concurrently the
managerial chairman of the co-op.
 
This was the measure for bringing ri people’s com-
mittees closer to production and raising their function and
leadership over the economic and cultural construction in
ri.
 
 
| Engels said that under socialism and Communism
“the government of persons is replaced by the administra-
tion of things, and by the conduct of processes of produc-
tion.”
 
 
Naturally, under present conditions in our country
“government of persons” is one of the important functions
of the ri people’s committees. But it must also be noted
that the function of “administering things and conducting
processes of production” is being increasingly extended.
 
Our Party took into account such actual conditions in
merging agricultural co-operatives into one in each ri and
appointing the chairman of ri people’s committee con-
currently the managerial chairman of a co-op.
 
In amalgamating agricultural co-operatives, our Par-
ty transferred the management of rural consumers’ co-
operative stores and credit co-operatives which had _ ex-
ercised their function independently in each ri to the agri-
cultural co-operatives.
 
This enables the agricultural co-operatives to organ-
ize and manage under a unified plan all economic affairs
from production to. distribution, exchange and consumption,
thereby accelerating the process of reproduction and further
improving the wellbeing of co-op members.
 
This is to meet the objective requirements for
enhancing the material interest of peasants and harvest-
ing farm produce in greater abundance by further promot-
ing marketing of commodities and money circulation in
the countryside.
 
Next, with the amalgamation, the range of activities
of agricultural co-operatives grew. Besides economic man-
agement, they now undertake educational, cullural, public
health and public welfare work,
 
 
58
 
 
This means that our agricultural co-operatives no
 
longer confine themselves merely to economic matters, but
pay attention to the whole aspects of peasants’ life and
assume responsibility for their life.
_ The extension of the range of activity of co-ops was
to meet the earnest desire of our peasants, who, subjected
to onerous oppression and exploitation for centuries, had
been most backward, to raise rapidly their cultural stand-
ard.
 
In this way, the Government, while conducting uni-
fied guidance over education, entrusts agricultural co-ops
with the management of schools.
 
This makes it possible to expand speedily the network
of schools of all levels, with little state expenditure and,
at the same time, this is of great significance for integrat-
ing production with education.
 
In his report to the Twenty-first Extraordinary Con-
gress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union, Com-
rade N.S. Khrushchov particularly stressed the necessity
of gradually transferring functions of government organs
to social organizations. And this is now being practised
in the Soviet Union.
 
It is to meet the demands arising in the development
of socialist society towards Communism that in our coun-
try the state has transferred much of its work to agri-
cultural co-operatives.
 
Organization of educational, cultural, public health
and public welfare work by agricultural co-operatives is
of particular significance for the growth of communist ele-
ments in the countryside.
 
When educational, cultural, public health and public
welfare establishments are provided to co-op members
free of charge for, as Marx noted, “the common satisfac-
tion of needs,” they are all embryos of Communism.
 
Management of educational, cultural, public health
and public welfare work by agricultural co-ops is of great
significance in preparing for the building of Communism.
 
The National Congress of Agricultural Co-operatives
held in January 1959, summed up the great victory in the
socialist agricultural co-operativization in our country,
 
 
59
 
 
set forth the tasks for further development of agriculture
and, at the same time, adopted new Standard Rules of
agricultural co-operatives.
 
With a view to hastening the completion of socialist
construction in the countryside and gradually preparing
for the building of Communist society, the new Standard
Rules provide for the further extending and strengthening
of the socialist co-operative ownership of the means of
production and the turning of them into ownership by the
whole people. |
 
Agricultural co-operativization was completed and
the third form, fully socialist, became the sole form of
agricultural co-operatives and share is distributed accord-
ing to the work done. On this basis, the Standard Rules
proclaimed land and all other means of production as the
socialist co-operative ownership.
 
The Standard Rules put an end to the private owner-
ship of land which had existed for several thousand years
and which was legally permitted even in the co-op of the
third form. All land owned by co-op members are brought
under common ownership according to the new Standard
Rules, and this is an epoch-making event in the historical
development in our country.
 
In the early days of the agricultural co-operative
movement, co-op members were allowed to some extent to
own privately draft animals and farm implements, when
they so desired, and in such case these were used jointly
by co-op members. But according to the new Standard
Rules draft animals and farm implements are placed un-
der common ownership, and the scale of side-line privately
run by co-op members and the acreage of kitchen garden
for co-op members were reduced markedly.
 
The aim of developing the co-operative ownership in-
to public ownership and the line of applying socialist
principle in production and distribution of share and pro-
moting Communist co-operation are laid down in the
Standard Rules.
 
The agricultural co-operative movement in our coun-
try has gone through the experimental stage, mass devel-
opment stage and the stage of completion in its progress,
 
 
60
 
 
These stages were determined by the different speed
and form of the movement. Therefore, they do not repre-
sent any changes of co-ops in their quality and character.
 
Viewed from the point of social and economic devel-
opment, the five years of the progress of our agricultural
co-operative movement from the experimental stage to the
stage of completion was a historic period when the private
ownership of the means of production was converted into
co-operative ownership and exclusive dominance of the
socialist agriculture was established in the countryside.
 
The past five years was a period of sweeping revolu-
lionary transformation of production relations, a period,
as Comrade Kim Il Sung noted, marked by the rapid de-
velopment of productive forces, further consolidation of
the co-operative economy, swift improvement of peasants’
life and the high spirit of our peasants. During this period,
the foundation was laid for developing our agriculture to
a higher stage.
 
The position of our agricultural co-operatives has
been radically changed. Our agricultural co-operatives are
iow in a position to introduce gradually up-to-date
machines and technique into their common economy.
Moreover, the agricultural co-operatives are not related
with the private capitalist elements and small commodity
products, as the agricultural co-operativization and soci-
alist transformation of private commerce and industry
were completed simultaneously.
 
In production and supply of commodities, our agricul-
{ural co-ops deal only with state-operated bodies and
enterprises and are related with other co-operative economy.
 
The character of our agricultural co-operative econo-
my has undergone changes and developed in many
spheres. Our co-ops today are different from and far more
advanced than the co-ops of the third form.
 
This progress was not made in a day.
 
Our agricultural co-ops underwent constant quantita-
tive and qualitative changes in the course of its develop-
ment. The progress of our agricultural co-ops has been
made possible not only by the changes and development
 
 
61
 
 
within agriculture itself but also by the all-round changes
and development of our society and economy.
 
With the changes in the scale and character of agricul-
tural co-operatives—this represents a stage of fresh pro-
press of the agricultural co-operative economy—brighter
prospects are opened up for the development of agricultural
productive forces in our country.
 
== For Further Upsurge in Agriculture ==
A high tide of socialist construction is sweeping our
country, and the entire working people are pressing ahead
on a winged horse, in response to Party’s call.
 
The First Five-Year Plan (1957-61) under which the
total value of industrial output is to increase 2.6 times, is
expected to be fulfilled within 1959, more than two years
ahead of schedule.
 
During the first two years of the current First Five-
an Plan, that is, in 1957 and 1958, our industrial output
 
oubled.
 
 
On the occasion of the tenth anniversary of the Demo-
cratic People’s Republic of Korea in September 1958, our
Party, on the basis of the achievements in socialist con-
struction and the high revolutionary zeal of the working
people, advanced prospective tasks of turning our country
into an advanced socialist industrial country.
 
The prospective tasks envisage a big leap forward in
the production of major industrial products in the next six
or seven years: output of electric power, is to increase
2.6 times; coal, 3.6 times; pig iron and granulated iron,
9 times; steel, 8-9 times; cement, 4 times; chemical fertiliz-
ers, 3.3-4.3 times; and fabrics, 4.6 times.
 
When these tasks are carried out, the per capita out-
put of electric power will reach 2,000 kwh, coal 2,500 kg,
pig iron and granulated iron 400 kg., steel 300-350 kg.,
cement 500 kg., chemical fertilizers 150-200 kg., and fabrics
more than 50 metres,
 
Determined to carry out the huge tasks presented by
the Party earlier than scheduled, our working people are
 
 
63
 
 
displaying inexhaustible creative energy in their strenuous
endeavour.
 
 
In order to hasten the completion of socialist construc-
tion and preparations for gradually going over to Com-
munism, our agriculture must keep pace with the rapidly
developing indusiry.
 
The primary tasks now confronting our agriculture
are to accomplish the technical and cultural revolutions in
the near future and thereby further strengthen and develop
politically apd economically the socialist co-operative eco-
nomy and turn our rural villages into rich, modern, soci-
alist villages where modern technique is employed in the
farming.
 
 
Material and technical foundation of our agriculture has
been strengthened considerably, but the technical reform
was lagging behind the economic transformation,
 
 
Until now our agricultural co-operatives have dis-
played their superiority primarily on the basis of handicraft
technique. But today our agricultural co-ops find it im-
possible to ensure a bigger upsurge in production, unless
they are furnished with modern technique.
 
 
It is clear that our advanced socialist co-operative
economy can no longer base itself on backward handicrait
technique. Therefore, the technical revolution, with the
building of irrigation systems, mechanization and electri-
fication as its main contents, is presented as the most
urgent and central task of our agriculture.
 
 
The completion of agricultural co-operativization, ex-
tension of the scale of the co-operatives, consolidation of
their economic foundation and the building up of the bases
of heavy industry—all this presents the technical revolu-
tion in the countryside as matured task. Consequently, our
Party set the following targets: putting the entire arable
land under irrigation within 2-3 years, mechanization of
agriculture within 4-5 years, electrification within 1-2 years.
And the state took steps for mobilizing agricultural co-
operatives for successfully implementing these tasks.
 
 
64
 
 
While the construction of big-scale irrigation projects
and work on the hydro-power stations were undertaken
with state funds, the Party has encouraged the agricultural
co-operatives to build medium- and small-scale irrigation
projects and power stations. Then the Party saw to it that
the co-ops with sufficient economic foundation should
secure modern machinery and equipment including tractors
and lorries.
 
 
Such measures are the manifestation of the Leninist
principle on the full display of the creativeness and active-
ness of popular masses in socialist construction.
 
 
Irrigation is the keynote of the technical revolution
 
in our agriculture, Irrigation is of decisive significance in
increasing agricultural products under the condition in
which rice cultivation on paddy-fields holds a most im-
portant place and a long drought and frequent floods occur
in spring and summer.
_ Indeed, Lenin’s words that “irrigation is needed, a-
bove all, as it transforms or revives the border region,
buries the past, and accelerating the transition to social-
ism” fully meets with the reality of our country. (Lenin’s
Collected Works, Vol. 32, Russian ed. p. 297.)
 
 
Now that the irrigation of paddy fields has been, in
the main, completed thanks to the consistent measures
taken by the Party for the expansion of the acreage under
irrigation, the cardinal task of irrigation lies in rapidly
establishing the non-paddy irrigation system.
 
 
Only by doing so can we swiftly increase grain harvest
on the non-paddy fields which occupy over two thirds ol
the arable land and at the same time develop simultane-
ously and on a full scale the branches of industrial crops,
stock-breeding, pomiculture and sericulture.
 
 
The September (1958) Plenum of the Central Com-
mittee of our Party set forth the task of completing the
irrigation system on all arable land with the exception of
steep slopes within the next 2 or 3 years.
 
Already over 10,000 projects, including the state
 
 
65
 
 
sponsored big-scale irrigation project in Kiyang (the acre-
age under irrigation will cover 51,000 jungbo), Ujidon
(34,000 jungbo) and in the Yalu River basin (95,000 jung-
bo), are under way. During the past 6 months from the
September (1958) Plenum to the spring of this year, reser-
voirs, pumping stations and other irrigation facilities for
irrigating 377,000 jungbo were built. As a result, by the
end of June 1959 the total acreage of irrigated land in our
country had reached over 800,000 jungbo. Thus, the nation-
7 task of irrigation in the countryside has been fulfilled in
e main.
 
 
Remarkable success has also been attained in the field
of mechanization of farm work.
 
 
The many-sided development of agriculture, wide ap-
plication of the advanced intensive farming methods, un-
dertaking of big-scale irrigation projects and other rural
construction and the sharp increase in the volume of
transport that followed co-operativization—all this brought
about an acute shortage of labour, farm machines and
transport facilities in the countryside.
 
 
Without mechanization of major farming and tran-
sport work the continuous growth of agricultural produc-
tion and vast scale construction could not be successfully
ensured.
 
The acreage of farm land (excluding slopes with a
12 degree gradient, swamps and siony fields), on which
mechanization can be introduced, amounts to some
1,400,000 jungbo.
 
At least 30,000-35,000 tractors and 25,000-30,000 lor-
ries are needed for the overall mechanization of basic
farming work and heavy transport work in the rural areas.
 
This year 5,000 tractors and 2,500 lorries will be sent
to the countryside, most of which will be Korean-make.
And within the coming 4-5 years the need for tractors and
lorries will be fully met.
 
A number of agricultural co-ops have already pur-
chased tractors and lorries and the network of farm ma-
chine hire stations continues to expand. The number of
farm machine hire stations increased from 59 to 80,
 
 
66
 
 
So far, the agricultural co-ops used modern farm
machines of the state farm machine hire station, But in
future the co-operatives will possess modern farm machines
fcr themselves.
 
Many ex-servicemen and the junior and senior middle
school graduates who had worked in the co-ops have been
dispatched to farm machine hire stations and state farms
to be trained as tractor drivers and mechanics. In this
way, the mechanized work teams have been organized in
the co-ops, and a full scale readjusting of fields is now in
progress.
 
It is expected in the coming 2 or 3 years labour power
needed in the rural areas will increase at least 2-fold.
 
Hence, it is the urgent problem to raise rapidly lab-
our productivity by widely introducing medium- and
small-scale mechanization in combination with large-scale
mechanization.
 
In our agriculture, paddy-field farming holds an im-
portant place. The land is undulated and slopes are very
steep. Intensive cultivation such as mixed-crop and furrow
cullivations has been in long practice. The differences of
natural and economic conditions vary greatly according to
the localities. Accordingly, it is of great significance to con-
trive and popularize various kinds of farm machines, parti-
cularly, simple medium and small farm implements suit-
able to the actual condition.
 
For the completion of irrigation and mechanization in
ie countryside, electrification should be pushed ahead ol
-hem.
 
According to the preliminary investigation, for elec-
trification of the countryside 920 million kwh of elec-
tricity will be needed, 5 times more than the power the
countryside consumes at present. It is estimated that big
power stations will supply 580 million kwh while the re-
maining 340 million kwh will be produced at 8,600 medium
and small power stations of agricultural co-ops. These co-
op power stations will have a capacity of 20 kw on an
average.
 
At present, the construction of medium- and small-
scale power stations in every rural village along with such
 
 
67
 
 
big-scale hydropower stations as Dokrogang, Kangge and
Woonbong, is being pushed ahead briskly.
 
Our country is abundantly endowed with water power
and other electric resources. And the construction of
large-scale water conservancy projects have been carried
out. Thus favourable conditions are provided for power
generation.
 
Already more than 800 power stations had been built
during the four months from September 1958 when the
construction of medium- and small-scale power stations
started in the countryside.
 
It is planned that this year the rural villages will be
supplied with ‘equipment and machinery to build some
6,000 medium- and small-scale power stations. Then the
electrification of the countryside will be completed in the
main by 1960.
 
Proceeding from the fact that the foundation of co-
operatives has been consolidated and the living standard
of the co-operative members as a whole improved, the new
Standard Rules of the co-operatives provide for raising the
common reserve funds from ‘10-15 per cent to 15-30
per cent or more for the successful implementation of
technical revolution.
 
In the meantime, the Party and Government took steps
to help the co-operatives increase their accumulations.
 
From January 1, 1959, the rate of taxes-in-kind was
lowered from 20.1 per cent to 8.4 per cent on an average,
and its amount is fixed. And it will eventually be abolished
in the future.
 
It has been the consistent line of our Party io develop
a diversified agriculture with the stress on the grain pro-
duction, widely introducing the advanced intensive farm-
ing methods and actively pushing forward irrigation pro-
jects, mechanization and electrification in the countryside.
 
Our Party put forward the militant tasks of increasing
the output of farm produce in the near fulure: grain
to 7 million tons, cotton to 200,000 tons, meat to 400,000
tons, cocoons to 60,000-70,000 tons, fruit to over 250,000 tons.
These figures show an increase of some 2 times in grain,
4 times in cotton, 4.4 times in meat, 8 times in cocoons and
 
 
68
 
 
2 times in fruit compared with 1958, In this way, our rural
ae will provide a rich food base and a raw material
ase.
 
Only with such rapid development of agricultural pro-
duction in a diversified way, it was possible to eradicate
completely the backwardness and onesidedness seen in our
agricultural production, to bring about balanced develop-
ment of industry and agriculture, to meet the varying re-
quirements of the population, and to raise the income of
cooperative members. In the past, our agriculture concen-
trated exclusively on raising the grain crops and failed to
solve even this.
 
Now that the grain problem has been solved and the
technical transformation of agriculture is being carried out
on full scale, favourable conditions for developing the co-
operative economy in a diversified way have been created.
 
Our Party has set the tasks of raising paddy rice out-
put per jungbo to 10-15 tons, maize to 4-5 tons, wheat to
3-4 tons, and cotton to 3-4 tons within the coming 2 or
3 years.
 
To this end, wide application of the advanced intensive
farming methods—irrigation, deep ploughing, close plant-
ing, liberal fertilizing and sowing of best-quality seeds—is
most important.
 
In the light of the fact that the acreage of arable land
in our country is limited, such intensive farming methods
are of decisive significance.
 
If we plough more than 30 cm deep (10 cm in the
past), apply an average of 500 kg of chemical fertilizers
per jungbo (200 kg in the past) and 50 tons of compost
(10 tons in the past) within the next 2 or 3 years and further
raise planting density of all crops, harvest can be immen-
sely increased.
 
The cold-bed rice seedling method which is a great
technical innovation in the cultivation of paddy rice should
be developed further. If 300 seedlings are planted to one
pyong, each seedling will sprout 6 branches and each ear
will bear 80 grains of rice on an average, Taking the
weight of 1,000 grains as 25 grams, the per pyong yield
will reach 3.6 kg or 10.8 tons per jungbo. A harvest ot
 
 
69
 
 
more than 5 million tons of rice can be expected from only
900,000 jungbo, Then pcople will be supplied more than
enough with rice and flour as their principal food.
 
In 1958 there were some co-ops, that harvested 55 tons
of rice per jungbo, 18 tons of maize, 4.5 tons of wheat,
6.7 tons of cotton. And it can be safely said that these high
yields can be surpassed.
 
To cite one example:
 
The Dooam Agricultural Co-operative, Kangnam
County, South Pyongan Province, gathered 55 tons of
paddy rice per jungbo on a 1.5 jungbo experimental plot.
To do this they ploughed the field only 20 cm deep, applied
75 tons of compost per jtuungbo and transplanted 133 cold-
bed seedlings per pyong. But suppose they plough 30 cm
deep, apply 100-200 tons of compost and transplant over
250 cold-bed seedlings, there is no doubt that the per
jungbo yield of rice will go yet higher.
 
The same thing is true with maize, wheat, cotton and
other crops.
 
 
In the field of stock-breeding, too, our Party set the
tasks of increasing the number of domestic animals: cows
from 660,000 to one million, pigs from 1.4 million to four
million, sheep and goats from 150,000 to 600,000-700,000.
These figures will be attained within the next two or three
years, while raising the annual output of meat to
400,000 tons, milk to 460,000 tons and eggs to 1.5 billion.
Thus, per capita production of meat will be 40 kg, milk
46 ke and eggs 150.
 
For the rapid development of stock-breeding, the most
lagging field in our agriculture, main efforts have been
concentrated on the joint stock-breeding by the -o-opera-
tives and on establishing firm fodder bases. For this pur-
pose two-crop cultivation will be extensively introduced
and fodder fields will be expanded to 500,000-600,000
jungbo in 3-4 years.
 
A number of measures have been taken to bring about
a new change in sericulture, pomiculture and apiculture
and in fresh-water fish breeding.
 
While emphasizing the development of agricultural
 
 
70
 
 
production, our Party is actively promoting rural construc-
tion, above all, productive construction.
 
Office buildings, building material production estab-
lishments, metal-working shops, wood-working shops,
warehouses, facilities for processing agricultural products
will be built in the countryside. Furthermore, it is expected
that within the next 4 or 5 years 800,000 dwelling houses,
school buildings with over 2,800 class rooms besides kin-
dergartens, creches, clubs, hospitals, restaurants, stores,
bath houses and cultural establishments will be built or
improved.
 
It is also expected that by 1963 the amount of common
reserve funds of all agricultural co-operatives throughout
the country will stand approximately at 4.4 billion won.
Only some 700 million won, that is, 16 per cent of the total
amount of common reserve funds, will be needed to build
all these schools, dwelling houses and cultural facilities.
This bespeaks that our agricultural co-operatives can carry
out the cultural construction programme in parallel with
the productive construction.
 
In the meantime, by 1961 per household share will
reach over 2 tons of grain and over 1,000 won in cash on
an average. This will enable all the co-operative members
to purchase a modern dwelling house on easy terms.
 
The basic task of the cultural revolution for raising
the level of general knowledge and technology of the entire
 
easants is also being successfully carried out.
 
The compulsory three-year middle school education
system has been put into effect, starting from November
1958 and the universal compulsory two-year technical edu-
cation system will be enforced in the very near future.
 
The preparatory work for enforcing the universal com-
pulsory technical education system ahead of schedule is
now going full fledge in every rural village, while teachers
for technical schools are being trained in special courses
attached to the higher educational institutions and higher
technical schools.
 
At the same time, large numbers of co-operative mem-
bers are studying in working people’s schools and working
people’s middle schools which were set up to raise the
 
 
71
 
 
general educational level of the entire peasants above the
level of the elementary school or junior middle school
eraduates.
 
All these facts indicate that the tasks of the cultural
revolution in our country are being successfully carried out.
 
 
<nowiki>*</nowiki> *K *«
 
 
Today the entire peasants of our country have risen
up as one for the implementation of the programmatic tasks
laid down by Premier Kim Il Sung at the National Con-
press of Agricultural Co-operatives and the entire working
class is giving powerful support to them.
 
In the course of discussing the Letter of the Party
Central Committee sent to the entire Party members in
September, last year, and the measures for implementing
the tasks set forth at the National Congress of Agricultural
Co-operatives, the revolutionary enthusiasm and creative
activeness of farmers have been heightened more than ever.
 
They have set up higher targets for increased produc.
ticn than the state plan and are putting up a
strenuous struggle to carry them out.
 
There is no shadow of doubt that our co-operative
members will victoriously carry out, under the correct
guidance of the Workers’ Party of Korea and with the
powerful support of the working class, the magnificent
plan for socialist rural construction drawn up by the Cen-
tral Committee of the Workers’ Party of Korea headed by
Comrade Kim I] Sung.
 
The harder our peasants work, the higher the produc-
tive forces will rise. The higher the productive forces rise,
the sooner we will reach the eminence of socialism.
 
Looking forward to the bright future leading to Com-
munist society where the principle of “from each according
to his ability, to each according to his needs” operates,
our peasants are marching vigorously toward Com-
munism.
[[Category:Library works about the DPRK]]
[[Category:Library works about the DPRK]]
[[Category:Library documents from the DPRK]]
[[Category:Library documents from the DPRK]]

Revision as of 15:09, 26 July 2024

Great Victory in Agricultural Co-operativization in DPRK
AuthorKim Han Joo
Written in1959
PublisherForeign Languages Publishing House
SourceInternet Archive

Foreword

The historica] cause of agricultural co-operativization was viccoriousiy carried out in our country in only four or five years after the task of the socialist transformation of agriculture had been set forth at the 6th Pienum of the C.C. of the Workers’ Party of Korea convened immediately after the truce.

Having completely healed the severe war wounds in a short space of time by relying on the advantageous co- operative economy, our agriculture is now making rap‘d advance.

The question of food which was most difficult in the early days following the truce and the prob:em of poor peasants, the most urgent ones at that time, have been completely solved, doing away with the source of exploita- tion and poverty once and for all in the countrys:de.

The agr:cultural policy of our Party in the posi-libera- tion days is a siriking demonstration of the correctness of Marxism-Leninism which teaches us that the land reform, a task of bourgeois democratic revolution, is no more than the first step for solving the question of peasants, though it is of great historic significance, and that revo:ution in the countryside must be pushed up to a higher stage so as to carry out the agricuitural co-operativization, a task ol socialist revo.ution, for the final solution of the question.

Lenin said: “Such great changes in the life of tens of millions of people, affecting the deep foundation of I?fe and custom, as the changing from small-scale, ind‘vidual peasant economy to the joint cultivation of land, can be brought


5


about only through long-drawn efforts andin_ general they take place only when the people are forced by neces- sity to rebuild their life.’ (Collected Works of Lenin, Russian Ed., Vol. 28, p. 318)

In our country, too, preparations for agricultural co- operativization had been fully made in line with the correct agricultural policy of the Party after liberation, and the movement for its realization started at a time when desire of the peasants for it became more urgent.

So it made unprecedentedly rapid progress, and was completed in a short space of time without a hitch,

The great achievement attained in the socialist transformation of agriculture means the victory of the agricultural policy our Party has consistently pursued since liberation.

Preparatory Stage of Agricultural Co-operativization

Until liberation, Korea remained a backward colonial, semi-feudal agricultural country.

Japanese imperialists and a smal] number of land- lords, only some 100,000 households, or 3-4 per cent of the total peasant households, owned 2,600,000 jungbo of land, or 60 per cent of the total arable land. While most of the peasants, 2,400,000 peasant households with little or no land, or 80 per cent of the total peasant households, were tenant farmers under the condition of semi-serfdom, Farm rent usually exceeded 50 per cent of the harvest, and some- times it reached 70-80 per cent. More than 70 per cent of the peasant households ran out of food for three or four months every year, while less than 20 per cent of the peas- ant households had sufficient food.


The capitalist sector in agriculture found its expres- sion somewhat only in some fruit growing, livestock breed- ing and ginseng cultivation. The rich peasant economy also was insignificant and most of the rich peasants as- sumed the character of semi-landlords.


The merciless exploitation by the Japanese imperialisis and feudal landlords inevitably brought about a general standstill of the agricuitural produciive forces and the im- poverishment of toiling peasants.

The deep-rooted contradiction in the countryside con- stituted one of the major causes which led the Korean peo- ple to the anti-imperialist, anti-feudal national liberation struggle. The land and peasant question was a most im- portant question in our revolution.


Consequently, it was taken up as a most important re-. volutionary task in the Ten-point Programme of the Fatherland Restoration Association which was organized and led by Comrade Kim I] Sung and other staunch Com- munisis. Greatly inspired by th’s programme the broad peasant masses in Korea, together with the progressive work:ng class, rose up more valiantly in the anti-imperial- ist, anti-feudal national liberation struggle.


However, until the country was I'berated by the great Soviet Army, the merciless colonial plunder and feudal ex- ploitation had continued in the countryside and the peas- ants had not been abie to secure land and freedom.

Foilow:ng the historic August 15 Liberation, the Kore- an peop:e were provided with conditions enabling them to tae eee independent country in accordance with

eir will.


After liberation, under the guidance of the Workers’ Parity of Korea, the tasks of anti-imperialist, anti-feudal democratic revoiution were successfully carried out in North Korea where favourable conditions were provided by the presence of the Soviet Army and the country’s economy was put on a new footing.


The Land Reform carried out in March 1946 was of great importance for promoting the country’s revoiution. Land owned by the Japanese, Japanese organizations, pro- Japanese, national traitors and the Korean landowners in excess of 5 jungbo, and all the land not tilled by the own- ers were confiscated without compensation. The confiscated land was distributed without compensation to the hired farm hands and the peasants who owned litt!e or no land. The number of work-hands and family members determined the sizes of piots in distribution. Abou! one million jungbo or 53.8 per cent of the total arabie land was confiscated, of which over 980,000 jungbo was distributed to 720,000 toil- ing peasant households.


Although the land was not nationalized, it must be pointed out that the land reform was most drastic in the method of confiscation and distribution.


8


Owing to the land reform, not only about 30,000 land- lords were liquidated as a class but the landlord-like rich peasants were hit hard. The proportion of rich peasants which had accounted for about 5 per cent of the entire peas- ant househo'ds was decreased to 2-3 per cent. The colonial, feudal landownership was thoroughly liquidated and the land was given to the toiling peasants in conformity with the principle, “tillers shall own land.”


At the time when the land reform was carr‘ed out, the land owned by the state—the land owned by the People’s Commitiees—was only 18,000 jungbo or less than one per cent of the total arabte land. |


It was eloquent proof, first of all, that the Party and the people’s power took into consideration above everything else the toiling peasants’ urgent desire for, and interest in, the land reform. It also showed that theze existed no large scare cap‘talist economy in our agriculture which could be turned into -state farms. Oniy about 2,700 jungbo of orchards confiscated from landiords was all that con- stituted the major material foundation of state-owned soci- alist agriculture in our couniry.


Since there was no large-scale Junker economy in Korea in the pre-libevation days, let alone modern capital- ist agriculture, very few farm implements and draught animals were confiscated. Only the irrigation facilities confiscated from the Japanese imperial'sts and landiords were all which came into the ownership of the State and came into the use of the peasanis.


In short, some confiscated orchards and irrigation faci- I'ties constituted the material foundation for the socialist sec‘or in the field of agriculture immediately after the land reform.


Accordingly, nothing like a co-operative economy could be expected at the time. This is quite understandabie.

Small commodity economy, based on the land owner- ship of the toiling peasanis, was dominant in our agricul- ture. It can be seen more clearly in the following table:

[table]

Following the land reform, nationalization of major industries was put into effect in August 1946 in the nor- thern part of the country. As a result, industry, transport, communications, banks, etc. formerly owned by Japanese imperialists and comprador capitalists were, unlike in the field of agriculture, put under the state ownership, that is, the ownersh’p of the entire people. Consequently, the ratio of the socialist economic sector became predominant in these fields, doing away with the relations of capitalist exploita- tion.

In industry, the private capitalist elements held an insignificant position and the co-operative economic sector came into being and began to grow.

[table]

Thus, the people’s democratic system established through the democratic reforms after liberation was put on two different economic foundations: the socialist econ- omic sector in industry and the small commodity economic sector in agriculture.

Lenin said that the socialist revolution in the country where the majority of the population consist of small peasants can be accomplished only by a series of special, transitional measures which are not necessary at all in advanced capitalist countries where the hired work-hand constitutes an overwhelming majority in industry and agriculture.


It was necessary to take a series of transitional measures in our country, too.

- As Marxism-Leninism teaches us, after the proletariat took the power into their own hands, it was necessary for the socialist transformation of small scale individual farming to develop industry to some extent which would supply farm implements, fertilizers, and other technical means to the countryside, and to enhance the political, ideological level of the peasants. .

Industry in the North, the level of which had been low, was badly damaged by the Japanese imperialists at the time of their surrender. There was only a small number of technical personnel, and raw and other materials were insufficient. Moreover, the country was. divided inio two parts owing to the U.S. occupation of South Korea. Accord- ingly, a certain time was required for an all-round restora- tion of industry. Besides, many ind:vidual peasants were at a low level, politically and ideologically.

Under these conditions, small commodity economy in agriculture was destined to hold its leading position for a considerable length of time.

However, this did not mean that our agriculture was to develop along the capitalist path.


1


The tasks at the time confronting the people in the North were of a transitional character, that is, gradually go:ng over to socialism by developing the national econ- emy in a planned manner by relying on large-scale na- tional:zed industries, while extending and developing the resulis of democratic reforms. |

In order to restra'n the growth of the capitalist sector in agriculture, the Workers’ Party of Korea took a series of measures: the acreage of farm land an individual peasant could own was limited to 5 jungbo; buying and selling, mortgaging and renting of land were strictly prohibited; when the owner of land became unable to till it himself, he must hand it over to the local People’s Committee to be disir:buted to the peasants with little land.(This land was equivalent to the state-owned in its nature and called the “leasehold.’’)

These measures, together with the thorough-going land reform, created very favourable conditions for the socialist transformation of agriculture.

For strengthening the economic relations between urban and rural districts, the system of tax-in-kind and a new credit system were introduced and the state-operated and consumers’ co-op trade network was newly set up and expanded.

Following the democratic reforms, the rehabilitation and deve:opment of the national economy made rapid strides. As for agriculture, it shook off its feudal land- ownership and began to receive positive aid from socialist industry. As a result, already in 1948, grain output in the Norih exceeded the pre-war peak by 10.4 per cent. The North, once a provision-short area, was turned into a zone with surplus food.

From 1946 to 1949, the total agricultural output value increased by 51 per cent; of which grain increased by 40 per cent, cotton by 407 per cent, animal products by 85 per cent, silk cocoons by 193 per cent. Our agriculture cou!d meet basically the demand of urban inhabitants and industry. In other words, a balance was reached to a cer- tain extent between industry and agriculture. However, the mutual relation was not yet closer. This can be explained


12


by the fact that our industry was at the stage of rehabili- tation, and, accordingly, its demand on agriculture was not so great.(In 1949, of the total industrial and agri- cultural output value, industry rated at 53.3 per cent.) On the other hand, agriculture kept relying on the individual peasants’ small commodity economic sector, backward in technique.


Before liberation over 60 per cent of Korea’s total industrial output was from North Korea, while only 30 per cent of marketable rice and 20 per cent of marketable wheat and barley came from North Korea.

Though more grain was available for marketing in the North with the growth of agricultural production after liberation, its amount was limited. It was inevitable that the rapidly growing industry would sooner or later find itself in contradiction with the economic foundation of individual farming. Moreover, it was self-evident that long-drawn backwardness in livestock breeding.and in cul- tivation of industrial crops—the former held five per cent and the latter two per cent in agricultural produce in the days of Japanese imperialist rule—would not be easily eliminated under small commodity economy. What is more, under the small-scale, scattered individual peasant econo- my, it would be impossible to improve to a great extent the peasants’ living and to do away with the source of ex- ploitation and poverty- once and for all in the countryside.


Thanks to the land reform, most of the poor peasants and hired farm hands, who had constituted the overwhelm- ing majority of the peasant population, became middle peasants to be the main force in the countryside. How- ever, there still remained some poor peasants, about 25 per cent of the peasant households, possible object of ex- ploitation by the rich peasants and profiteers.


While giving material aid to the poor peasants and struggling against exploitation, the Workers’ Party of Ko- rea took steps to establish the state farms and stock farms and farm-machine hire stations which would play a lead- ing role in transforming agriculture in socialist way and


13


show the broad peasant masses the advantage of large- scale farming and mechanization of agriculture.

During the three-year long war unleashed by the U.S. imperialists and traitorous Syngman Rheeites, our agriculture suffered greatly as our industry did. Rural vil- lages were destroyed or burnt down, over 90,000 jungbo of farm land was lost and a great number of irrigation projects and river dikes were destroyed. The number of draught animals was reduced to about half compared with the pre-war days. Supply of chemical fertilizers, farm implements and various kinds of daily necessaries was sharply cut down.

But our agriculture, even under the most difficult con- dition of war, not only successfully met the demands of both the front and the rear but advanced steadily towards socialism.

In view of the severe devastation the industrial es- tablishments suffered in urban districts, the Party con- centrated its main forces on agriculture. To meet the war difficulties squarely and restore the agricultural productive forces, the Party and Government, relying on the aid given by the peoples of the Soviet Union and other fra- ternal countries, widely encouraged the joint labour’ or- ganization such as the ox-share and labour-exchange teams which had long been practised by the peasants in our country, while expanding greatly the state farms and stock farms and the network of farm-machine hire stations.

Already in the peaceful construction period before the war, the Party and Government began to set up state farms and stock farms by bringing grass and fallow land under cultivation and on the basis of some livestock farms and orchards confiscated in accordance with the Law on Land Reform. However, it was during the war time that the state farms began to make rapid develop- ment mainly for the purpose of rapidly restoring the severely war-damaged livestock breeding and supplying the front with necessary meat.

There were 16 state farms and stock farms including seven orchards covering an area of some 6,000-7,000 jungbo in the pre-war days. But there were 213 in 1953


1-4


with an area of more than 57,000 jungbo, including the province-run farms and stock farms. They played a great role for the rehabilitation and development of livestock breeding and fruit growing, meeting the demands of the front. Besides, these farms and stock farms newly establish- ed by rationally utilizing the fallow lands and mountain slopes provided the war refugees with jobs and made them settle down.


It was in the spring of 1950 when the farm machine- hire stations appeared. By 1953 their number increased from 5 to 15. The number of tractors increased from 150 to 500 (in terms of 15 h. p.).


During the war time, the peasants organized on a wide scale joint labour in various forms.


In the light of the difficulties created by the shortage of labour power, draught animals and farm implements, it was positively encouraged to rationally organize ox-share and labour-exchange teams on the principle of mutual aid and co-operation. As a result, from 1951 on, their signifi- cance and role were further heightened. The entire peas- ants came to realize through experience more keenly that without a closer co-operation in labour, successful farm- ing in the war time was impossible. Consequently, in many districts, not only in the farm work but also in side-line production, a new form of cooperative labour, not merely of temporary, seasonal nature but of the year-round, be- gan to emerge. And at the end of 1952 the Party and Gov- ernment decided to organize and develop gradually side- line co-operatives among the peasanis as one of the mea- sures for improving the economic situation of poor peas- ants and fishermen. Moreover, financial and material aid was given to the newly organized co-operatives, a higher form than the ox-share and labour-exchange teams.

Though the number of the side-line co-ops in the countryside at that time was not big, some of them went beyond the livestock breeding and other side-lines, and began to extend gradually their collective activities to farming.

During the war time, in Kangwon Province, especial-


15


ly in the districts near the eastern and central fronts, num- bers of the front joint work teams were organized.

The front joint work teams which were organized mostly with the young and middie-aged peasants after their families had been evacuated worked on the land while aiding the front all they couid. In their initial stage, it must be pointed out, the front joint work teams had no rigid rules and reguiations about governing themseives, but the teams gradually came to assume the spec‘fic fea- tures of co-operative economy from production to distri- bution. Membership of the teams ranged from 50 to 200. The front joint work team represented an embryonic co- op which emerged when the war was raging in fuil force.

By July 1953 when the Armistice Agreement was sign- ed, they grew into 174 agricultural co-ops (of which 72 were sideline co-ops) embracing 2,400 peasant househoids.

Mention should be made of the fact that all these socialist forms in the rural economy such as the state farms and stock farms, farm machine-hire stations and a- gricultural co-ops in embryo made further deve:opment in the course of the war, and, overconi?ng difficulties, made a great contribution to the growth of agricultural produc- tion in the war time. Grain output in the second year of the war was greater than in the first year, and that in the third year bigger than in the second year. Socialist agri- culture made great contribution to increase grain output and was a positive factor in promoting the socialist trans- formation of agriculture. All these results, as Premier Kim Il Sung remarked in his “For the Rehabilitation and Development of the Post-war National Economy,” were at- tained thanks to the agricultural policy of the Workers’ Party of Korea in the early days of the war for a gradual conversion of the scattered individual farming in- to co-operative one while developing the state farms.

Development of Agricultural Co-operative Movement

Objective Requirement for Socialist Transformation of Agriculture and Actual Conditions for the Development of Agricultural Co-operative Movement

When the just Fatherland Liberation War against the armed aggression of the U.S. imperialists and Syngman Rheeites ended in an historic victory for the Korean people, the people in the North were confronted with the most important and difficult task of speedily rehabilitating the severely devastated national economy and developing it in order to lay a foundation for a_ self-supporting national economy and improve rapidly the deteriorated people’s living conditions.

For carrying out this task, the Workers’ Party of Korea laid out the general line of giving priority to the development of heavy industry while simultaneously de- veloping light industry and agriculture. Agricultural co- opera.ivization was one of the most important prere- quisites for carry:ng through this general line.


During the war the material and technical foundation of agricui:ure had been severely destroyed and there existed a serious shortage of labour power and draught animais. It was obvious, thevefore, that so long as the in- dividual farming remained as it was, it was imposs’b‘e to hope for the rapid development of agricultural production and solve the food question, an acute problem that we faced after the cessation of hostilities. Nor could the priori-


17


ty growth of heavy industry and rapid development of light industry be ensured, nor the development of the na- tional economy as a whole speeded up. (The gross agricul- tural output value in 1953 decreased to 76 per cent com- pared with the pre-war year of 1949, of which grain drop- ped io 88 per cent, vegetables to 58 per cent, cotton to 23 per ceni, fruits to 72 per cent and-silk cocoon to 58 per cent.)


In the post-war period, with the enormous aid from the Soviet Union and other fraternal countries, our indus- tries have been rapidly reconstructed, far bigger in their scope than before, and equipped with up-to-date machines.


Under these circumstances, agriculture had to keep pace with the qualitative changes taking place in the field of industry.


On the contradiction between industry and agriculture which was becoming acute in the post-war days, Comrade Kim Il Sung pointed out as follows: “Thus the contradic- tion between the socialist industry and the individual peasant economy was pregnant with the danger of creat- ing a grave disproportion between the rapidly recovering; developing and qualitatively changing industry and the rural economy which was. being rehabilitated at a snail’s pace in the postwar situation prevailing in our country.” (On the Victory of Socialist Agricultural Co-operativization and Further Development of Agriculture in Our Country)


Under the condition in which the peasants’ living had deteriorated to the exireme and the individual farming existed, it was impossible to solve the question of poor peasanis, the most acttie one in the postwar days, and to do away with the source of exploitation. During the war our agriculture was further deteriorated and the number of poor peasants increased to about 40 per cenit of the total peasants. In this situation, agricultural co-operativization was the only way out of predicament for our peasants. With agriculiural co-operativization alone, it was possible to overcome the lack of labour power, draught animals and


18


farm implements and all other difficulties, and ensure the rapid rehabilitation and development of agricultural pro- ductive forces and enhancement of the peasants’ living standards.

Unless agriculture had been placed under a socialist system, it would have been imposs‘bie to successfully re- model enterprisers, tradesmen, and handicrafismen in ur- ban districts, who, though they were small in number, were closely related with individual peasants. (In 1953, the private capitalist and small commodity economic sectors held 3.9 per cent in the gross industrial output value, and 32.5 per cent in the value of retail trade.)

Agricultural co-operativization was, therefore, a law- governed requirement for social, economic development in the transitional period.

The 6th Plenum of the Central Committee of the Workers’ Party of Korea held in August 1953, laying down the basic line for the post-war national economic recon- struction and development, put forth the historic task of agricultural co-operativization.


However, it must be pointed out that the agricultural co-operativization movement was launched under very unfavourable conditions, that is, the war damage was great, the country remained split, and there was hardly any farm machines to speak of.

In this difficult period, the Party took the policy of agricultural co-operativization. It was a most timely poli- cy. Should such policy not have been taken after the war because our revolution was at the stage of anti-imperial- ist, anti-feudal democratic revoluiion so far as the whoi:e of Korea was concerned and because we lacked heavy in- dustry to provide agriculture with modern machines, it is quite obvious what the results would have been.

To be sure, there were some who coniended that agri- cultural co-operativization was premature. They used to say: “Our country still remains split,’ “We have no farm ma- chines,” and so forth.

First of all, they did not fully understand what the lawful objective requirement had arisen inthe course of the devel-


19


opment of the national economy in the northern part of the country, and that unless the democratic base in the North, the source of our revolution, was strengthened poli- tically, economically and culturally, the country’s unifica- tion is quite imposs’ble.

Socialist construction in the North, including agricul- tural co-operativization, is an inevitable requirement aris- ing in the course of the social and economic development in the North.

South Korea has not been liberated yet, but we can- not stop a forward movement in the North and wait for the liberation of South Korea. Nothing can hold back the revolution and social, economic development in the North. Only by strengthening further the democratic base in the North by carrying out socialist construction, can the coun- try’s peaceful unification be accelerated.

Second, they did not understand fully our peculiar con- ditions of land and agricultural production. Without co- operativization, the introduction of mechanization and ad- vanced technique would be impossibie in our couniry.

Such dogmatic, formulistic views were severely cri- tisized in time by the Party.

This should not be taken, however, to mean that the division of the country and the technically low level of agriculture presented no adverse condition to the agricul- tural co-operativization. To a certain extent they did. But they were not fatal factors which could make the agricul- tural co-operativization imposs’ble.

In launching the agricultural co-operative movement in the North, the Party took account of the necessity and matured conditions for the movement.

Premier Kim I] Sung said, “The agricultural co-opera- tive movement is a reflection of matured conditions at the present stage of the development of ihe country and the lawful, objective requirement of social development.” (For the Rehabilitation and Development of the Post-war Na- tional Economy, Korean Ed., p. 346)

There were favourable conditions for agricultural co- operative movement: the people’s democratic power was established in the country; the socialist industry was


20


playing the leading role in the national economy; and the land reform and other democratic reforms had been thoroughly carried out and especially the worker-peasant alliance strengthened through the ordeal of the Fatherland Liberation War. Moreover, since the peaceful construction period before the war, such socialist form of economy as the state farms and stock farms, farm machine-hire sta- tions, consumers’ co-ops, peasants’ banks, etc. had come into being in the countryside. Then there were such po- pular joint work teams as the ox-share and labour-ex- change teams, which had a long standing in the country- side, from which the co-operative economy began to emerge, Furthermore, the enormous material and technical aid given by the Soviet Union and other fraternal coun- tries enabled us to use their rich experiences of agricul- tural co-operative movement to good advantage.

Marxism-Leninism teaches us that under the small peasant economy, ‘as a rule, it is impossible to fully intro- duce modern farm machines and up-to-date technique.

So long as the land owned by peasants was too small and the individual peasant economy prevailed, the introduc- tion of machines and advanced farming method was hampered. Had we waited the comp:etion of mech- anization before we started co-operativization, it would have brought about a stagnation in agriculture and eventually bankrupicy.

Therefore, the agricultural co-operativization could not be postponed until the completion of industrialization and mechanization.

To be sure, industrialization would provide favoura- ble conditions for agricultural co-operat:vization. How- ever, when we take into account the peculiar conditions of our country, it was the only correct and practical way to effect agricu!tural co-operativization in conform¢ty wih the matured objective requirement, create favourab.e conditions for mechanization of agriculture and then acceierate soci- alist industrialization.

As everyone knows, co-operative labour, no matter how simple it may be, is far superior to scattered, indivi- dual labour. Marx pointed out in the Capital as follows:


Zl


‘Not only have we here an increase in the productive power of the individual, by means of co-operation, but the creation of a new power, namely, the coliective power .of masses.” And it was Lenin who said that the transition from individual peasant economy to joint economy will raise labour productivity 2-3-fold and save 2-3-fold in man-power,

In the post-war days it was urgent to rapidly restore and develop agriculture. To cope with the situation our peasants had to take the advantage of co-operative labour. Taking this actual situation into full consideration, our Party put forth the task of carrying out agricultural co- operativization prior to industrialization, However, this should not be taken to mean that technical revolution was neglected in completing socialist transformation of agricul- ture. The Party, putting forth the task of agricultural co- operativization, paid special attention to the development of heavy industry for technical reform in all branches of the national economy including agriculture. At ihe same time it was expected to receive up-to-date farm machines from the Soviet Union and other socialist countries.

Party’s Policy on Agricultural Co-operativization and Its Successful Implementation

Embarking upon the road of co-operativization, the Party had to direct serious consideration to the following special circumstances. Peasants had little experiences in organizing and running the co-ops, their cultural and tech- nical standards were low, and the private ownership of land was still in effect.

Consequently, the Workers’ Party of Korea took the road of organizing several co-operatives in each county while preserving the private ownership of land and other means of production. And as experiences were accumulat- ed, co-ops were organized on an extensive scale.

It must be pointed out that the Party, in guiding the


22


co-operative movement, paid profound concern towards the attitude of all strata of peasants.

The basic class policy of the Party in rural] areas was to rely firmly on the poor peasants, strengthen the alliance with the middle peasants, and to restrict and remould the rich peasants. At the time when the co-operative movement was started, the stratum of peasants was divided into poor and middle peasanis, its ratio being roughly 40:60. During the war, the rich peasants dropped from 2-3 per cent to 0.6. Most of the middle peasants were those who came into being after the land reform.

Poor peasants who realized the importance of joining the co-ops came out most strongly supporting the co- operativization, and most of the middle peasanis, too, readily approved co-operativization from the start. How- ever, there were some middle peasants who, wavering and hesitating, sat on the fence, while the rich peasants were indifferent or hostile to the policy.

To those wavering middle peasants the Party used the means of explanation and persuasion, letting them see everything with their own eyes. Towards the rich peasants, the Party strictly prohibited the practice of ex- ploitation, but kept the door open for those who sincerely wanted to work as socialist working people. The Party took necessary steps to take sanctions against the small number of rich peasants who were trying to undermine the co-operative movement,

Lenin’s program for agricultural co-operatives and the historic experience of the Soviet Union showed that it was of importance for developing the co-operative movement to correctly define the forms of co-operative economy on the principle of combining the individual interests with the common interests in accordance with the development of agricultural productive forces.

Hence, our Party, taking into consideration the ex- periences in the People’s Democracies and turning to ac- count the forms of ox-share teams and _ labour-exchange teams, formulated the three forms of agricultural co- operative in accordance with different extent of prepared- ness and economic status of peasants,


23


The first form was the permanent mutual-aid team. In this case work is done jointly but the land is individually owned. This is an embryonic socialist form.

The second form was the semi-socialist form. In this case the land is pooled for common economy and over 80 per cent of incomes are distributed to the members ac- cording to the number of work-days and 20 per cent ac- cording to the size of land contributed.

The third form is a complete socialist form. In this case the land is turned into co-op ownership and incomes distributed only according to work done.


The draft animals and farm implements were not turned into co-operative ownership automatically. It was according to the wish of the owner whether they belonged to the co-ops or remained in private ownership, However, draft animals and farm implements were used for muiual benefit and duly paid if they were turned into co-operative ownership.


The three forms of agricultural co-operative and the method of pooling the means of production clearly reflect the policy of our Party on completing the co-operativiza- tion by firmly relying on the poor peasants and consoli- dating the alliance with the middle peasanis.


At the initial stage of the co-operativization, our Party adhered to the principle of the gradual development of co-ops both in form and size, “from an elementary form to an advanced one and from a small scale one to a large scale one.” But rejecting a mechanical interpretation of the principle, the Party instructed that if the level of the consciousness of the peasants was high and managerial personnel were well prepared, it was possib:e and neces- sary to form from the beginning a co-op of the advanced form on a comparatively big scale.

In organizing agricuitural co-operatives, the Party adhered strictly to the Leninist principies, white tak ng every precaution against wrong tendencies. Some co-ops were only interested in the rapid quantitative growth and advanced forms of co-operative in contravention of the voluntary principle and mutual benefits. Then there were


24


some who took such attitude that; the co-operative move- ment should take iis natural course, not comprehending the growing demand of the peasant masses. It was of tremendous significance for the future development of the co-operative movement that co-ops were organized with the poor peasants and the most active e'ements in each locality, and that the Party and Government concentrated their leading forces on making these first co-ops register a great success in production, thereby demonstrating by examples the advantage of the co-operative economy to the broad masses of peasants.

The per unit area yield of grain of over 1,000 co-ops organized on ‘an experimental basis during the period 1953-54, was 10-50 per cent higher than that of individual farming, and their cash ‘incomes 2-7 times bigger.

The agro-stock and agro-fishing co-ops organized in mountainous and coastal areas where poor peasants made up a greater proportion also registered a great success, adhering to the slogan of the Party: “Make the best use of the mountains and the seal”

Though such excellent results were achieved by the co-ops at the experimental stage, some deviations and shortcomings cropped up. Some leading personnel in agri- culture revealed impetuous tendencies, while others took a passive attitude towards the creative zeal of peasants for organizing co-ops. Then there were some who, on the plea of strict adherence to voluntary principle, chose to sit down and wait for the organization of co-ops to take place spontaneously.

In some villages, where there had been already two or three co-ops organized, some contended that no more co-ops were needed.. Even there were some cases where the newly organized co-ops were refused reg'stration for several monichs.

Such conservative tendency was also revealed in de- ciding ihe form and size of co-ops. In some rural areas, sticking to the “principte” of distributing shares according to the land invested, some leading personnel demanded that the third form of co-op which the peasants had set up at their own will be reorganized into a second form. And


25


there were some who maintained that the membership of a co-op should not exceed 20 to 30 households.

Such conservative tendencies at the experimental stage were not without reason.

Some.imes the policy of organizing several co-ops in each county on an experimental basis was mechanically interpreted. Then there were some cases when the lead- ing personnel lacked a deep understanding of the inner life of the new co-op. They fell short of experience and knowledge necessary for guiding the co-ops.

Undesirabie tendencies, however, were not limited to the leading personnel. In one or another shape, they were also found among peasants. Illustrative of this was their failure to observe the principle of mutual benefits.


Excess was to be noted in turning or not turning the land, draft animals and means of produciion into co- operative ownership in accordance with the rules. When the privately-owned preperty was placed under co-opera- tive ownership, there were cases when correct evaluation and compensation were not duly made.

Also shortcomings were found in management, Some co-ops, without careful consideration of their economic foundation, invested a large sum of fixed capital in build- ing facilities beyond their power or bought large-size farm machines, and wasted money and materials for non- productive purposes. There were cases when the co-ops attempted to run too big a factory or go into trade on the pretext of running a side-line business.

There were many more cases of this nature differing only in degree: violation of the principle of democracy in management, lack of planning in the organization of pro- duction and labour, levelling in calculating workdays and distributing shares, improper control of common pro- perties, utter negiect or excessive accumulation of joint funds, etc.

Our co-ops have come to see, through their own ex- periences, and thanks to the guidance and assistance of the Party and government organs, what harmful con- sequences would be entailed by those shortcomings and


26


defects, and worked out proper measures to correct such shortcomings and defects. Neediess to say, root:ng tien Ou: wds a major question to be dealt with. Experience in the first year of co-ops proved valuable for the further de- velopment of co-operativization. On the basis of the tre- mendous achievements scored at the experimental siage, the co-operative movement developed on a mass scale from 1955, with the mass influx of middle peasants, the main body of the rural population, besides poor peasants. Co-operatives embraced 1.2 per cent of peasant households at the end of 1953 to 31.8 per cent at the end of 1954, then to 44.7 per cent in the spring of 1955.

With the rapid development of the co-operative move- ment on a mass scale, many deviations and negative phenomena cropped up in the organizational work. The major deviations were to be seen in the hasty “leftist” tendencies in the work of organizing and guiding co-ops. In some places, the organizational work was done not in- frequently in an administrative manner or in a “hot-and- cold” fashion on the pretext of overtaking and surpassing other districts.

Some leading personnel organized recklessly some large-scale co-ops on the ground that it would tend to “simplify” the guidance work, underestimating the lower forms of co-op or encroaching upon the inierests of indivi- dual peasanis on the plea of co-operative’s interest.

Negative phenomena also appeared among the peas- ants themselves, reflecting the frame of mind of the middle peasants; some peasanis with comparatively stable econo- mic foundations organized co-ops exclusively among themselves refusing admittance of poor peasanis; the acreage of kitchen gardens was expanded in violation of the rules, some able-bodied members of a family were re- fused to join the co-op. And they tried to raise the evalua- tion beyond market prices of draught animals, farm im- plemenis and others which they coniributed to the co-op.

There were even cases when some hostile elements taking advantage of the mass organization of co-ops, wormed iheir way into them to occupy leading positions under the guise of active peasants.


27


For the purpose of rapidly making riddance of the above-mentioned deviations and negative phenomena manifested in the organization of co-ops. and ensuring a steady development of the entire co-ops, our Party put forward its basic line of ensuring both the numerical growth and qualitative consolidation of co-ops and com- pleting socialist transformation of agriculture. As the co- operative movement entered the new phase of mass devel- opment, the most urgent question was consolidation of the co-ops organizationally and economically.


It was of prime importance for the qualitative consoli- dation and steady development of co-ops to solve the question of cadres, including the chairmen. The cadre pro- blem became further complicated due to the fact that many rural Party members and cadres trained and brought up during post-liberation period were killed during the war.


Considering the source of managerial personnel should be found among the co-op members, our Party ap- pointed as managerial cadres active members who enjoyed the confidence of peasants and who had rich experiences in farmirig, and particularly, the beleft families of patriotic martyrs, servicemen’s families, and ex-servicemen, Also, special concern was paid to training and reeducating them at the central or provincial co-op managerial cadres’ schools, and raising the level of their business ability through short courses and experience-swapping meetings.


At the same time, to make the managerial cadres be- come true servants of the people, to establish the mass style of work and to bring their work closer to production, the desk work was simplified so that the cadres could partici- pate in production.

Historic experience in the agricultural co-operativiza- tion in the Soviet Union showed that success or failure of a collective farm depends on who stands in the van and leads the work of the collective farm. Therefore, our Party directed the main force of the Party and Government to the guidance work to young co-ops. Social?st order and system were to be established in the rapidly growing co- ops, production to be increased gradually, the life of mein-


28


bers to be improved and the Party’s position in rural areas to be consolidated further.

To this end, the principte of correctly combining the day-to-day guidance with the intensive guidance was ad- hered to, and the central guidance with the local gui- dance.

However, in the early period of the co-operative move- ment, the guidance work could not keep pace with the rapid changes taking place in the countryside.

Under these circumstances, the Party rendered every assistance to the leading workers to correctly understand the inner life of the co-operative and acquire relevant eco- nomic and technical knowledge. And this helped greatly the local Party and government organs to give better guidance to the co-ops. Yet, it was far from removing the discrepancy between the rapid quantitative growth of the co-ops and their qualitative changes.

The most effective method of solving this question was intensive guidance, which the Party conducted on a nation-wide scale once or twice a year by mobilizing thou- sands of leading workers of Pyongyang and local dis- tricts. |

In this way, the Party succeeded in exposing and correcting negative phenomena, Any distortion of the co- operativization policy was corrected, abie managerial cadres were selected and allocated, democratic princ‘ples were put into practice fully in the co-ops, socialist labour discipline and the rational system of distributing shares were firmly established, the planned development of co- ops was enforced, and the members’ socialist ideology and consciousness were enhanced. At the same time, through this guidance work, the managerial staff of the co-ops raised the level of political and managerial work. And the Party and government workers who were mobilized for this work acquainted themselves fully with the inner life of the co-operative, enabling them to become more com- petent in the guidance work. |

The struggie for implementing the decis'on of the December 1956 Plenum of the Party Central Committee, which is of historic significance in the post-war socialist


29


construction, brought about also an epoch-making change in the field of guidance of co-ops. The Party d:spatched Presidium members of the Party Ceniral Committee and other Party and government leaders to co-ops. They dis- cussed with ihe co-op members the successful fulfilment of the arduous tasks of the First Five-Year Plan (1957-1961), learn'ng what difficulties and other urgent questions the co-op members faced and what would be the best way to overcome the difficulties and solve the questions. This served as an important factor in bringing about the epoch- making upsurge in agricultural production. Bureaucratic, formalistic leadership and conservatism formerly observed in the field of guidance of the rural economy were shatier- ed to pieces and the creativeness and inventiveness of the masses of the co-op members were stimulated greaily.

Proceeding from the principle that the main task of co-ops is to raise the yield of agricultural produce and members’ incomes by organizing economic activities cor- rectly, greater concern has been paid to the reasonable utilization of natural conditions including land and the constant growth of labour productivity. Under the cir- cumstances in which each co-op member owned no more than 0.9 jungbo of land on an average, they should turn the co-operative economy into the best use. Every poss:bie help and guidance was given to raise per unit area yield by adopting the principle of planting proper crop on proper soil, raising the land utility rate and introducing widely various advanced intensive farming, and at the same time to develop in a diversified and planned way farming, live- stock farming, sericulture, fruit growing and fishery under the naiural and economic conditions of the locality.

In order to st'mulate enthusiasm for greater produc- tion and material interests of co-op members measures were taken for reorganizing the emulation drive of the past, i.e. under individual economy to meet the new situa- tion. Moreover, a wide-scale movement was started for establishing model agricultural co-operatives. A new sys- tem was established; when work teams and sub-teams overfulfilled production assignments, those teams were to be awarded in kind and cash. Contrary to this, when they


30


did not fulfil their plans, a certain number of workdays were deducted.


In order to relieve the women members, whose num- ber was more than half of the co-op membership, from their everyday household chores, more day-nurseries, kindergariens, laundries, d-ess-making shops and other public service establishments were built. All this greatly improved the working conditions for the women members. And it must be added that these measures which had not been seen at the experimental stage showed a new develop- ment in the co-operative movement.


Particular attention was paid to keeping the balance between accumulation and expenditure of the co-ops with a view to consistently carrying out the extended reproduc- tion and guaranteeing the systematic enhancement of the living standards of co-op members.

Proceeding from the principle that, until co-op mem- bers completely recover from war damages, first conside- ration should be given to the improvement of co-op mem- bers’ life and the consolidation of their econom’c founda- tion, the rate of reserve funds was limited below 5 per cent of incomes while greater shares were divided among co-op members.


Lenin stressed that every social system arises only with the financial] assistance of a definite class and ihe sys- tem which the socialist state must assist more than the usual is the cooperative system.


This theme of Lenin was of particular importance in the realities of our country where agricultural co-ops were organized and developed on the war ruins.

Under the guidance of our Party, the state investment in the rural economy increased steadily.


Altogether 120 million won was invested by the state in the fieid of rural economy between 1954 and 1958. Irrigation projects and river dykes were built, the net- work of machine-hire stations was extended and technical personnel in this field were trained in large numbers. In addition, the state appropriated enormous funds to re-


31


habilitate or construct chemical fertilizer factories and farm implements factories.

This made it poss’ble to lay and consolidate success- fully the material and technical foundation of the severely ruined rural economy in a short period after the war.

Besides, the state loaned over 300,000 tons of provi- sions and seed grains, and more than 243 million won of farming fund to economically weak co-ops and poor peas- ants. Moreover the state cancelled more than 160,000 tons of tax-in-kind and loaned grains and more than 14 million won of loan.


In 1956 a system of paying fixed amount of tax-in- kind was enforced throughout the country to lighten the burden of the peasants and raise their interests in produc- tion, reducing markedly the rate of tax-in-kind. Measures were also taken to reduce another 5 per cent of the amount of tax-in-kind in co-ops and considerably increase the purchasing price of agricultural produce,


In the post-war period the Parity and. government bodies sent tens of thousands of ex-servicemen and many junior and senior middie school graduates to the coun- tryside to relieve the acute labour shortage,

Moreover, every year in farming seasons numerous office employees, students and servicemen were mobilized to help with farming. Every year millions of workdays were given to the countryside.


All the successes won by our agricultural co-operati- ves in overcoming hardships and difficulties in the early post-war period cannot be imagined apart from the con- cern shown by the state.

The state has always given special favour to agricul- tural co-ops and at the same time has shown careful con- cern for individual peasants, too.

Along with the development of co-operative economy, measuves were taken to correct in time even the slightest tendencies to underestimate individual peasant economy. And co-ops gave private peasanis every possib‘e assistance, materially and technically. This greatly conduced to bringing individual peasants into the co-ops.


32


From ithe experiences gained in the process of or- ganizing agricultural co-ops we have learned the following facts:

Firstly, the level of political and ideological con- sciousness of co-op members and the sbservance of prin- ciple of voluntariness in organizational work exerted decisive influence on the work of co-ops. Agricultural co- ops organized with politically and ideologically prepared persons on the principle of strict voluntariness achieved successes from the early days of organization and deve- Icped rapidly. On the other hand, some co-ops. organ- ized in violation of these principles failed to set up discipline and order, their production was also meagre and unity of ideology and will among co-op members was lacking. There were even a few isolated cases of members leaving the co-ops.

Secondly, abiliiy and responsibility of the managerial personnel of co-ops and iheir popularity among the masses constituted decisive factors for the development of co-ops. The co-ops run by able and responsible cadres achieved great successes in production. In such co-ops, discipline and order were well established and things moved along in a planned manner. However, some co-ops run by in- compeient cadres gained nothing but negative results.

Thirdly, it is importani to take into consideration the preparedness of co-op members, and the ability of the ménagerial cadres in particular, in deciding the size of co-ops. The too big co-ops organized in the early days and those which had been expanded into too big ones after their formation made progress at a snail’s pace because of in- ability of the managerial cadres and irrational organization of labour. Subsequently measures were taken for dividing too large co-ops into smaller ones and for merging too small co-ops inio larger ones, based strictly upon the voluntary will of the co-op members. Special attention was paid to the merger of small co-ops in particular. The co- ops which were unable to develop further because they were so small in size, or those co-ops in which rational farming was impossible because their land and irrigation facilities were interlocked, were merged, The premature merger at


a3


the managerial personnel’s judgment was strictly prohibited.

Fourthly, the enemy within the co-ops is more dan- gerous than those without.

Fifthly, it was revealed that the organizational, political activities of the Party organizations and the role of the Party members in co-ops were of great significance for strengthening the co-ops.

Sixthly, the co-ops in which the local Party organiza- tions and Government organs had promptly corrected defects made rapid development. But those which were otherwise remained in a backward state.

From the experiences accumulated in the management of the co-ops we have learned the following facts:

First. Most important in consolidating and developing agricultural co-ops organizationally and economically is ensuring democracy in every way. In such co-ops where the members, as the masters of the co-ops, had taken part positively in the work of the co-ops and democracy had been ensured, everything went along without a hitch re- sulting in a rapid development of co-ops. On the other hand, there was a small number of co-ops where democracy had not been ensured. In such cases the co-ops lagged behind.

Second. Great difference was to be noted in harvest and income between the co-ops that set up the production plans in conformity with the natural, economic conditions and organized efficiently the work, and the co-ops which did the contrary.

Third. Rational organization of labour, strict labour discipline, the correct calculation and assessment of work- days and rigid observance of socialist remuneration system constituted key factors for the development of co-ops, In such co-ops where all this had been well observed labour enthusiasm of the co-op members reached a high level, labour productivity was stepped up and eventually all the work carried out in time. But, in the co-ops where no such principles were observed the results were very negligible.

Lastly, if the co-ops reaped better harvests and raised incomes compared: with the time when the members had been individual farmers, and compared with the neighbour-


Jd


ing individual peasants they produced a good effect on them. It promoted the desire of the individual peasants to join the co-ops, while strengthening the unity of the co-op members. On the contrary, such co-ops, though small in number, which failed to raise their harvest and incomes had a bad effect on the neighbouring individual peasants.

At the stage of mass development of agricultural co- operative movement, more valuable, abundant experiences were accumulated than at the experimental stage, which constituted a sure guarantee for the further development of the agricultural co-operative movement.

The Third Congress of the Workers’ Party of Korea convened in April 1956 set forth the task of bringing the agricultural co-operative movement to a successful con- clusion. It was at such a time when socialism was taking the offensive in all branches of the national economy.


In order to complete agricultural co-operativization at the earliest possible date, our Party was greatly concerned about the rich peasants who remained outside of co-ops, while concentrating guidance on such districts where the rate of co-operativization was low.


As of June 1956, while about 80 per cent of the total peasant households were embraced in co-ops in North and South Pyongan and South Hamkyung Provinces, the rate of co-operativization was 56 per cent in Jagang Province, a mountainous district where the villages are scattered and geographical conditions are unfavourable, 44 per cent in the neighbourhood of Pyongyang where the peasants were interested in trading and 42 per cent in Kaesong and its neighbourhood, newly liberated area. Some peculiarities were to be noted in Kaesong and its neighbouring villages. The area had not been so long under the people’s democra- tic system, for they had been liberated not long ago and had some peculiarity in landownership and other aspects.

In view of such situation, the Party had to carry out the organizationa] work in the mountainous areas, city suburbs, and newly liberated areas. The problem of rich peasants who still remained outside the co-operatives had to be solved.


35


In mountainous areas, measures were taken to organize small-scale independent combined work teams taking into account the fact that the people were living scattered and to set up joint livestock farms to bring together the peasants who lived far apart from each other.

In the rural villages adjacent to towns, where the affairs of individual peasants were closely linked with private traders, agricultural co-operativization was carried out in parallel with the socialist transformation of the ‘in- dividual traders and enterprisers.


Taking into consideration the fact that in the newly liberated area the political and cultural level of peasants was generally low while the desire for the private land ownership was comparably sirong, the Party concentrated efforts on penetrating the policies of the Party and Government among them. In particular, efforts were directed to smashing the intrigues designed by such anti- Party and anii-revolutionary elements as the overthrown landed gentry, capitalists and pro-Japanese elements, and Wiping out the evil consequences therefrom, while streng- thening the work of bringing up the nucleus members. Moreover, the Party helped the co-operative members choose a form of co-operatives which is most suitable to their aciual situation.


As for the rich peasants, as already mentioned above, the Party observed the principle of remoulding them by peaceful means, instead of liquidation by the method of confiscation. This was possible because the socialist re- volutionary forces were strong, whereas the position of rich peasants was insignificant.


Along wiih the individual industrialists and traders in cities and towns, most of rich peasants came to realize through the practical experiences in the revolutionary and historical development in our country that the only way out was to become socialist working people. Never relaxing the education of the rich peasants, the Party concentrat- ed main efforts on consolidating the already organized co- operatives organizationally and economically, proceeding from the principle that “if the co-operatives are strength-


aft


ened and their members’ life is better than that of the in- dividual peasants, they will join the co-operatives of their own accord.” (From the speech delivered by Premier Kim Il Sung at the Meeting of Managerial Workers of Co- operatives in South Pyongan Province.) At the same time, the Party attached great importance to the co-operatives of low forms.


With the strengthening of the economic foundation of agricultural co-operatives as a whole and the collapse of the last foothold for exploitation in the countryside, the most stubborn rich peasants came willingly and volun- tarily into the co-operatives.


It confirmed once more the correciness of the Party policy on transforming rich peasants by peaceful means.


However, this is not to say that the socialist trans- formation in the countryside was carried out without a class struggle. On the contrary, it accompanied a severe class struggle. The overthrown exploiting classes did not give up the wild fancy of restoring the old system and the American imperialists nesting in South Korea and, their puppet, the Syngman Rhee clique were in a frenzy to carry out subversive activities against the northern part of our Republic. The class enemies resorted to every vile scheme to disintegrate the agricultural co-operatives from within and without: reactionary rumours vilifying the Party poli- cy on the agricultural co-operativization were spread, the joint properties of the co-ops were the targets of their production plans, and even attempts were made on co-op cadres’ lives.


Particular mention should be made of the fact that as the agricultural co-operativization was nearing completion and the victory of socialism was fortified in cities and the countryside, the machinations, sabotages and subversive activities of the counter-revolutionaries who lost their last foothold became all the more vicious. Consequently, the Party steadily waged vigorously a mass struggle a- gainst the counter-revolutionary elements, while strength- ening the political and ideological work among the peas-


37


ants for enhancing their socialist consciousness and re- volutionary vigilance.

In this way, every scheme of the enemy in the rural areas was exposed and smashed, while safeguarding the gains of socialism, enhancing the revolutionary spirit and political enthusiasm of peasants and fortifying them. with firmer confidence in the ultimate victory.

Experiences showed that only by suppressing the enemy who attempted to restore the old system and_ by taking appropriate measures against a handful of those elements who opposed the co-operative movement, could we promote the all-round development of co-operative movement and socialist transformation of rich peasants.

By the end of August 1958, the tasks laid down at the Party Third Congress to complete the agricultural co- operativization by the end of 1961 had been victoriously accomplished, And it goes without saying that all this was possible because of the Party’s correct agricultural co- operative line and its guidance in conformity with the concrete reality of our country.

The agricultural co-operativization also promoted the socialist remoulding of private traders and enterprisers in cities. With the co-operativization of the individua] peasant economy the capitalist elements in cities lost the last foot- hold. Thus, in our country the co-operativization of agri- culture and the socialist transformation of privaie trade and industry ran parallel and were completed almost at the same iime. And the fundamental question of the tran- sitional period, “Who will win?” had been completely solved in favour of socialism both in cities and rural villages.

The agricultural co-operativization was a great revolu- tion in our countryside. Small-scale individual peasant economy. based upon the private ownership of the means of production ihat had existed for thousands of years has been wiped out once and for all. And our rural communi- ties have been turned into socialist communities.

The completion of agricultural co-operativization made it possible to solve completely the contradiction existing between the large-scale socialist industry and small com- modity individual peasant economy and to ensure the


38


balanced development of industry and agriculture. And the economic relations between town and the countryside have been further strengthened.

In this way, the worker-peasant alliance, the political basis of our people’s democratic system and the basic motive power of our revolution, has been further consoli- dated on a new socialist basis and our Party’s position in rural areas and revolutionary democratic base in the northern part further strengthened.

Major Characteristics of Agricultural Co-operativization

The agricultural co-operative movement from the ex- perimental stage to the stage of completion in our country was, first of all, characterised by the rapid speed of develop- ment. Another characteristic is that an advanced type, the third form, of agricultural co-ops occupies an absolute majority.

[table]

As shown above, the agricultural co-operative move- ment in Korea maintained an unprecedentedly rapid tempo and the co-operativization was completed only in 4-5 years. Moreover, from the first days of the movement, the over- whelming majority of co-ops were organized in the third form. In August 1958 all co-ops took the third form. It must be pointed out that co-ops were organized with little techni- cal reconstruction of agriculture, but the agricultural co- operativization was carried out at high speed.


And then ihe agricultiral co-ops were organized on the basis of private landownership but the overwhelming majority of them took the third form from the initial stage of co-operativization.

This fact represents the most important characteristic of our agricultural co-operativization. All this was possi- ble, thanks ‘first of all to the high political consciousness and revolutionary spirit of peasants and because the align- ment of class forces was decisively favourable for agricul- tural co-operativization.


Particularly, it can be explained by the fact that dur- ing the great Fatherland Liberation War, preliminary con- ditions were created for the peasants to organize volun- tarily agricultural co-ops under the guidance of the Work- ers’ Party of Korea.

The Korean peasantry has a revolutionary tradition of fighting for land and freedom under Japanese imperi- alist rule. After liberation the peasants were tempered all the niore through the land reform and the hard trial of the Fatherland Liberation War.


In the course of the war they saw more clearly the barbarity of the U.S. imperialists and the reactionary nature of the landowner-bourgeois system which the U.S. imperialists were intending to force upon the Korean peo-

le. " Through the bitter class struggle against the U.S, im- perialists and Syngman Rhee clique and the resistance of


An


the overthrown exploiting class, the toiling peasants were more closely united around the Party and their revolution- ary spirit was unprecedentedly heightened. And, fully ap- preciating the cause of our revolution and the correctness of the Party’s policy, they had firm confidence that victory would be always with them if they followed the directives of the Party.

Under the guidance of the working class, the worker- peasant alliance was further strengthened and the Party’s position in the rural village consolidated greatly.

Though the Party lost many of its core members in the rural villages during the war, the Party trained a force of excellent Party members and reinforced Party organi- zations in every village by bringing up a new core of mem- bers among peasants. And the Party members in the rural villages stood in the van of agricultural co-operativization.

In the countryside, the revolutionary forces grew mightier, while the forces of opposition were extremely weak.

As mentioned above, the landowner class was liqui- dated and the rich peasant economy weakened in the course of enforcing the land reform. Moreover, the forces hostile to the agricultural co-operativization were all the more weakened in the process of the bitter class struggle during the war time.

This fact was one of the important conditions for accelerating the smooth development of agricultural co- operative movement.

The historical experiences of the great Soviet Union showed that for the socialist transformation of agriculture, first of all, the mass movement for collective farms should be waged among the peasants, and the peasants them- selves should be convinced of the advantages of collective farming and take this road of their own accord. To this end, the work should be carefully done. Of course, for this a certain length of time was needed.

Preliminary conditions for co-operativization in our country were already matured during the war time. Over- coming the difficult conditions in which manpower, draught animals and farm implements were in short, the peasants


4]


carried on successfully their farming by strengthening ox- share and labour-exchange teams. Most of them fully re- cognized the necessity and superiority of collective work


The rise of revolutionary spirit and political and ideo- logical level of the peasants, the steady growth of socialist sector in the countryside after the liberation, and enhance- ment of its leading role exerted great influence in helping the peasants to see the necessity and advantage of collec- tive work.


The organization of consumers’ co-operatives embrac- ing the broad popular masses in the countryside and the es- tablishment of peasants’ banks gave, to a certain extent, the peasants co-operative education and training in the field of commodity circulation and credit. With the expansion of state farms and stock farms and the machine-hire sta- tions, the advantages of mechanization of agriculture and large scale farming were vividly demonstrated.


The embryonic co-operative economy, which appeared for the first time during the war time, developed rapidly in the post-war period. As already mentioned, this fact is linked with the above-mentioned material and ideological foundations.


It should be-also pointed out that at the experimental stage of co-operativization, the first few agricultural co- ops organized in every county achieved great successes, demonstrating the superiority of co-operative economy.


The successes are linked with the specific features of landownership created by the land reform and small-scale farming. After the land reform the Party made it impossi- ble to turn the land into a means of exploitation or to con- centrate the land again into the hands of individuals. If a peasant, who had received land, could not work it, the Government put this land under the management of the local People’s Committees. In July 1953, such land totalled 530,000 jungbo, over one fourth of the total arable land.


Therefore private landownership by toiling peasants was fundamentally different from the private landowner- ship of the past.


42


It is, in essence, the transitional form of private Iand- ownership which should gradually and inevitably switch over to the socialist-collective ownership of the land.

The specific features of such landownership had no small influence on the conception of. the peasants about landownership.

The small and equal size of plots of land owned by the peasants must also be mentioned here.

Even after the land reform, their land was in general small owing to the fact that the area was limited, the land was distributed evenly among the peasants in accordance with the number of work hands and family members.

In July 1953 the size of plots of land owned by each peasant household was as follows: no more than one jungbo 32.9 per cent of the total peasant households; 1-2 jungbo 41.7 per cent; 2-3 jungbo 19.1 per cent; more than 3 jungbo 6.3 per cent; the average size of land cultivated by each household throughout the country was no more than 1.8 jungbo.

It must be noted that there was very little difference in the sizes of plots owned by peasants, Each peasant family owned on the average one jungbo in the paddy- field area; in the intermountain area, 1.0 jungbo; in the mountain areas, 2-3 jungbo.

The fragmental land owned by no small number of peasanis made it impossible to raise their living standard.

The weak side of individual farming was more vividly revealed during and after the war.

It was quite natural that many peasants actively joined co-ops in order to extricate themselves from the posilion of small individual peasant economy.

Equality in landownership which minimized the signi- feance of distribution for the contributed land in the co- ops and the revolutionary spirit of the peasants provided important material conditions for organizing the over- whelming majority of the third form of co-ops in the early days. : Tooether with the above-mentioned internal factors it


no


should be also pointed out that the enormous economic an 43


technical assistance of peoples of the Soviet Union and the other fraternal countries, and the introduction of their rich and precious experience into our agricultural co- operativization provided favourable conditions for the de- velopment of our co-operative movement.


When they started the socialist co-operativization the leading workers in the countryside and the peasants could under the guidance of the Workers’ Party of Korea un- hesitatingly take the only just direction—the direction taken by the peoples of the fraternal countries.

Correctly calculating on the conditions and factors for co-operativization which became gradually matured already in the period of peaceful construction after libera- tion and during the Fatherland Liberation War, our Party creatively applied Marxist-Leninist theory on the socialist transformation of agriculture in accordance with the ob- jective requirement of social economic development, and introduced rich experiences of the Soviet Union and the other fraternal countries in conformity with actual condi- tions of our country. Thus, the correct line was defined and timely measures were taken to give every possible guidance and assistance to agricultural co-operativization. Therefore, the co-ops in our country were able to develop at an unprecedentedly rapid pace and to achieve great successes.


When the agricultural co-operativization in Korea forged ahead at a rapid pace and the third form of co-ops occupied the overwhelming majority, some one hesitated complaining that “‘the speed of co-operativization was too rapid and co-operativization trespassed the interests of the middle peasants.”

But the rapid tempo of co-operativization and the overwhelming majority of the advanced form of co-ops were completely logical. There is no doubt that unless our Party had surmounted on time conservatism and passivity on the basis of the correct appraisal of actual conditions of the countryside, the task of agricultural co-operativiza- tion would not have been successfully, like today, com- pleted in 4 or 5 years after the war. It was shown in the


44


process of co-operativization of five years that even under the condition in which only handicraft technique without any modern machines and technique is dominant, agricul- tural co-operativization can be realized and even agricul- tural co-ops so organized can achieve a decisive superiority over private peasant economy.

It was shown that the landownership and the class- composition in the rural villages and ihe revolutionary spirit of the peasants constituted important factors for the speedy development of the agriculiural co-operative move- ment. And only with the high degree of enthusiasm of the peasants to carry out the Party’s correct policy, and the Party’s and government’s correct leadership and _ help, agricultural co-ops could be fully consolidated, even though they rapidly grew in quantity.

True, the victory of agriculiural co-operative move- ment in our country proved vividly the great vitality of the general principle of Marxism-Leninism on the socialist re- volution in the countryside and the correctness of agricul- tural policy of the Party which employed creatively this principle to our historic conditions.

Sharp Growth of Agricultural Productive Forces and Development of Agricultural Co-op System

In the post-war period, our Party directed its great force to the successfully carrying out of the agricultural co- operativization and, at the same time, to rapid rebuilding of the war-devastated material and technical foundation of agricultural production.

On the basis of the priority development of heavy industry and the advantages of the new relations of pro- duction established in the countryside, the Party and Gov- ernment waged the whole-Party and nation-wide struggle for sharply stepping up agricultural productive forces.


Having successfully fulfilled the post-war Three- Year Plan for the Development of the National Economy (1954-56), our industry witnessed a bigger upsurge from 1957, the first year of the First Five-Year Plan.


In 1958, the total industrial output value was 4 times that in the pre-war year of 1949, or 4.3 times that in the pre-liberation year of 1944.

In the five years of the post-war period, the total in- dustrial output value grew at an average annual rate of 42 per cent, the means of production increased on the average by 52 per cent annually and consumer goods by 34 per cent, Consequently, an end was put to the severe colonial onesidedness in industry, and the self-supporting foundation of the national economy was firmly established.

Rapid development of industry served as the most im- portant guarantee for swiftly rehabilitating and strength- ening the material and technical foundation of agriculture


46


and bringing about a great upsurge in agricultural produc- tion.

During the post-war Three-Year Plan period, our agri- cultural production topped the pre-war level thanks to the strugele for carrying out the decisions of the November 1954 and December 1955 plenums of the Central Com- mittee of the Workers’ Party of Korea. And it continued to develop rapidly on an extensive scale, bringing about an unprecedentedly upsurge.

In rehabilitating and strengthening the foundation of agricultural production, the Party attached prime im- portance to the construction of river dikes and irrigation systems which were essential for restoring from the damage caused by natural calamities and for increasing per-unit- area harvest.

57 per cent of the total sum of state investment in agriculture in the five years of the post-war period was spent for building river dikes and irrigation systems.

Along with the building of the large-scale projects with state investment, construction of medium- and small- scale river dikes and irrigation systems was widely un- dertaken by agricultural co-operatives.

During the five years of the post-war period, 629 re- servoirs and 1,659 pumping stations were reconstructed or newly built throughout the country. As a result, the paddy fields under irrigation increased from 227,000 jung- bo in 1953 to 463,000 jungbo.

Especially, the Pyongnam Irrigation System. built during this period alone supplies water to more than 40,000 jungbo of paddy fields.

The proportion of irrigated paddy fields to the total paddies rose from 52 per cent to 91 per cent during this period.

During the five years of the post-war period, con- struction of river dikes and breakwaters, anti-erosion pro- jects and afforestation work were also undertaken exten- sively to protect over 350,000 jungbo of farmland from the damage by flood and tidal water.

The number of machine-hire stations increased from


47


15 to 50, and the number of tractors (in terms of 15 h.p.) increased fourfold.

The Kiyang Farm Machine Factory and many other farm machine factories were reconstructed or newly built, and various kinds of efficient farm machines and imple- ments such as seeders, thrashers and fodder cutters were supplied in large numbers to the rural villages.

The Heungnam Fertilizer Factory and other chemical fertilizer factories were reconstructed in a short space of time from severe war-ruins and were expanded. The sup- ply of chemical fertilizers during the five years since the war increased 12 times.

Agricultural institutes, higher and secondary agricul- tural schools and courses for training agricultural experts were built and expanded on a large scale to meet the grow- ing demands for agro-technicians, while correspondence courses were opened in higher educational institutes and technical schools.

Under the co-operative economy, it was possible to in- troduce extensively advanced method of intensive farming and improve the distribution of crops on the principle of right crop on right soil.

In 1957-58, cold bed seedlings, which signify a tech- nical innovation in the battle for good rice harvest, were planted on 50 per cent of the total paddy fields. Introduc- tion of cold bed seedlings helped increase per-jungbo yield of rice by 1-1.5 tons compared with ordinary seedlings. Humus pot planting of cotton, an advanced method which more than doubles the per-jungbo yield, was applied to 70 per cent of the total area under cotton, The area sown to maize, a_ high-yielding crop, extended from 236,000 jungbo in 1954 to 826,000 jungbo in 1958, while utility rate of land rose from 125 per cent to 161 per cent.

Owing to these measures and the selfless endeavour of the peasants, total grain output kept on increasing— 2,870,000 tons in 1956; 3,200,000 tons in 1957; and a re- cord harvest of 3,700,000 tons in 1958. Grain harvest in 1958 was nearly double that in 1946, shortly after the liberation. | |


48


With the sharp increase of grain output, the food pro- blem, one of the acute problems in the post-war period, was solved in the main in 1957. We used to import annually hundreds of thousands of tons of grain. But today we have a surplus rice.

This is the most brilliant achievement of our socialist agriculture.

The sharp increase of grain output in our country has resulted primarily from the rise of per-jungbo yield of farm produce.

Extensive introduction of cold bed seedlings, expan- sion of the irrigated paddy fields, and generous manuring are the essential conditions for the increase of per-jungbo yield of grain. In 1956, the average per-jungbo yield of rice was 24.4 per cent higher than in 1954, and in 1958 it was 32 per cent higher than in 1954. Per-jungbo yield of maize increased by 30 per cent during the same period.

Many advanced agricultural co-operatives have gath- ered a good harvest inconceivable in the past.

Here are a few instances.

Dooam Agricultural Co-op, Kangnam County of South Pyongan Province, gathered on the average 13 tons of rice per jungbo from 160 jungbo of paddy field in 1958, and the harvest from 1.5 jungbo of an experimental plot reached 55 tons.

Samryong Agfticultural Co-op, Soonchun County of South Pyongan Province, harvested an average of 3.6 tons of maize per jungbo from 422 jungbo of field, and from 12 jungbo of field they reaped 18 tons per jungbo.

Wonsa Agricultural Co-op, Ongjin County of South Hwanghai Province, raised per-jungbo yield of wheat to 4.5 tons.

Big achievements have-also been registered in other branches. The Government has taken a number of mea- sures for markedly increasing the output of industrial crops, It has raised state purchasing prices of industrial crops, preferentially supplied chemical fertilizers and ex- empted the cotton growers from tax-in-kind.

In 1958 per-jungbo yield of cotton doubled that in 1953, and its total output increased threefold.


49


Livestock farming, which suffered most during the war-time, started making a good headway.

By September 1, 1958, the number of cattle in the country had increased 1.3 times that at the end of 1953, and that of hogs 2.8 times. Meat output grew 3.2 times during the five years of the post-war period.

Enormous achievements were also. scored in fruit growing and sericulture.

A nation-wide movement is under way for extending the orchard area by 100,000 jungbo during the First Five- Year Plan period.

More than 50,000 jungbo have been reclaimed for fruit growing. Total output of fruits in 1958 was 131,000 tons, or 1.8 times as much as the peak harvest in the pre- war days.

In 1958, we produced 8,700 tons of cocoons, or 1.6 times as much as the peak output in the pre-war days.

In this way, in the recent years extensive upsurge and innovation have been registered in grain production and in all other branches in the countryside where socialism has triumphed.

It must also be noted that, along with the high rate development of agricultural production, the structure of agriculture is undergoing change to meet the demands of the national economy.

[table]

From the above tables we can see that our agriculture has taken the course of many-sided development, with stress on grain. Agricultural production has been stepped up to supply raw materials to industry and to meet the growing demands of the population for meat and fruits.

Rapid growth of agricultural] production has led to the strengthening of economic foundation of agricultural co-operatives and swift improvement of the living of co- op members.

Until 1956 agricultural co-ops set aside on the aver- age about 5 per cent of their incomes for common reserves. But, as the living of the co-op members improved steadily, the rate of common reserve funds increased to about 10 per cent in 1957 and more than 15 per cent in 1958.

The total sum of commonly-owned property of our agricultural co-operatives last year was about 686 million won, or on the average 51,500 won for each agricultural co-operative, or on the average 650 won for each co-op household. Compared with 1955, the sum of commonly- owned property for each household increased 2.4 times on the average.

This serves to show that our agricultural co-opera- lives have laid the foundation necessary for steadily ex- tending reproduction and capital construction,

Our agricultural co-operatives have set aside an in- creasingly greater amount from their incomes and harvest for common reserve funds, seed, fodder, and grain to be exchanged with fertilizers. Nevertheless, the share of co- op members has increased systematically.

[table]

Shortly after the armistice, poor peasants accounted for about 40 per cent of the total peasant households. But in 4-5 years since then their living standards have been improved to those of middle peasants or above.

As the economic foundation of agricultural co-opera- tives has been consolidated and the living of co-op mem- bers has improved, construction of modern villages is undertaken extensively. Our rural villages are changing their looks with every passing day,

Many buildings for common economy such as stalls, silk-worm breeding rooms and stores, as well as large numbers of educational, cultural, public health and public welfare establishments have been built in our countryside. By the end of 1958, schools with over 8,000 class-rooms, 6,400 nurseries and kindergartens, 9,000 democratic pub- licity halls and clubs and many clinics, bath houses, bar- ber shops and laundries were built in the rural areas.

Tens of thousands of modern dwelling houses have been built in the countryside. By the end of 1958, eleciri- city had found its way to 67 per cent of the rural villages, one 49 per cent of the peasant households had electric light.

Many agricultural co-operatives have installed tele- phone service and through-wire radio system.

With the enforcement of universal compulsory pri- mary and middle school education and with the extensive adult education, cultural standard of peasants has rapidly improved and new socialist national culture is flowering in our countryside.

Over 50,000 cultural, art and physical culture circles involving more than one million peasants are now func- tioning in our rural areas. Ideological consciousness of peasants is being remoulded.

The entire agricultural co-op members, who have scored great victory following the path shown by the Party, are firmly determined to further strengthen and de- velop the co-operative economy and defend to the last the gains of socialism.

The outdated ideological remnants of a smal] property owner are gradually being eliminated from co-op mem-


o2


bers; and with the enhancement of the ideological con- sciousness of collectivism, unity and solidarity between co-op members have been further strengthened and our co-op membérs are taking an active part in joint labour and are displaying to the full their creative enthusiasm in socialist construction.

All this serves io show that agricultural co-operativi- zation has brought about a radical change not only in the relations of production, but also in the cultural and intel- lectual life of the people.


The basic line of economic construction of our Party in the post-war period and the Party’s agricultural policy are most correct and, to carry out this policy, the entire peasants under the leadership of the working class have displayed a high degree of patriotic enthusiasm and rendered distinguished labour service. Consequenily they could register such big achievements in agriculture.

To strengthen steadily the positive reaction of the relations of production upon the development of the pro- ductive forces—this assumes great importance in the economic policy of the Marxist-Leninist Parties.

In this connection Comrade Kim II Sung said:

“The socialist co-operative economy system, too, cannot pause at one place. It must develop and must be further strengthened.”

Since the first day of the agricultural co-operative movement, our Party has corrected in good time fac- tors impeding the development of production in the inner life of agricultural co-operatives, and improved and strengthened the system and order in agricultural co- operatives to meet the demands of the steady development of productive forces.

What assumed momentous significance in this con- nection was the amalgamation of agricultural co-opera- tives which was carried out throughout the country between October and November last year.

As has already been noted, in guiding the agricultural co-operative movement our Party has given particularly prudent atiention to the size of agricultural co-operatives.


53


When their size is. too small, agricultural co-opera- tives will not display to the full the advantages of the co-operative economy, and, on the contrary, when their size is too big, agricultural co-operatives will encounter ereat difficulties in the management of common economy.

Here is a table illustrating the growth of the average size of agricultural co-operatives in our country.


Average number of Average acreage of peasant households arable land culti- embraced inaco-op vated by aco-op

[table]

The average size of agricultural co-operatives has grown considerably in 4-5 years, both in the number of member households and in the acreage of arable land.


The growth of size of agricultural co-operatives re- presents the rehabilitation and strengthening of material and technical foundation of agriculture in the post-war period—expansion of the network of machine-hire stations and construction of many irrigation systems—and the marked enhancement of political and business standards of the co-op management personnel and the leading per- sonnel in the field of agricuiture. At the same time, this corresponded to the rapid development of agricultural co-operative movement.

In the course of mass development of the agricultural co-operative movement, many peasants joined the already formed co-ops, while the new co-ops were formed on a bigger scale than the co-ops formed at the early stage of


54


the agricultural co-operative movement. Consequently, the composition of co-ops in size changed remarkably.

[table]

By June 1955, co-ops with less than 30 member households had accounted for the greater part, while in June 1956 co-ops with member households of 31-50 made up the greater part, and since March 1957 co-ops with member households of 51-100 had occupied a greater pro- portion.

At the Conference of Agricultural Co-op Management Personnel of South Pyongan Province in January 1957, Comrade Kim Il Sung said that a co-op with 40-100 mem- ber households was in general a proper size under the conditions prevailing in our country.

A co-op of this size was appropriate at that time, for it could effectively cultivate its farmland mainly with handicraft technique, and the co-op could undertake join- tly certain side-lines.

At the experimental stage, the size of agricultural co-operatives in all districts of the country was almost


3)


the same—around 10-20 member households. But a mark- ed difference was brought about after the co-operative movement started mass development, Generally speaking, co-ops in the plain area assumed a bigger size than the co-ops in the mountain area.

This can be explained by the average size of co-ops in different provinces.

[table]

In North and South Pyongan Provinces which have large tracts of plain area, the average number of member households of a co-op is bigger than in the mountainous provinces of Jagang and Ryanggang. It is, therefore, self- evident that the natural-geographical conditions in moun- tainous districts where peasants lived far apart from each other and farmland was scattered, constituted the primary conditions retarding the speed of the development of the co-operative movement as well as the growth of the size of co-ops.

The comparatively small size proved to be no longer suited to the rapid progress of agricultural productive for- ces and to the further development of co-ops. It now be- came an obstacle to the rational utilization of land, improvement of labour organization, many-sided develop-


56


ment of the common economy and _ especially to the mechanization of farming. Under the condition of small scale co-ops, considerable waste and irrationality were found in the extensive rural construction.

Therefore, there arose before our Party the pressing task of opening up brighter prospects for the development of agriculture by eliminating the discrepancy between the comparatively small-scale agricultural co-operatives and the productive forces and by successfully carrying out the immediate tasks of technical and cultural revolutions in the countryside.

This was a fully matured task, because the organiza- tional and economic foundation of agricultural co-ops had been strengthened and the political and business standards of co-op management personnel had been raised consider- ably over the past five years, and because mass produc- tion of modern equipment and farm machines such as tractors and lorries started at home.

The amalgamation of agricultural co-operatives was a complicated task. Nevertheless, it was accomplished smoothly in 1-2 months with the unanimous support of the peasants.

As a result, more than 13,000 agricultural co-ops were merged into about 3,800, with the average number of member households of a co-op increasing from 80 to about 300 and the acreage of the arable land cultivated by a co-op was extended from 130 jungbo to 500 jungbo.

Consequently, agricultural co-operatives were provid- ed with the conditions for undertaking land construction on a full scale, more widely introducing modern farm machines and advanced farming methods, developing the common economy in a diversified way by making effective use of natural economic conditions, checking waste of labour power and materials in rural construction, and for pushing ahead with the rural construction in a planned way.

How then did the amalgamation of agricultural co-ops proceed?

Agricultural co-operatives were merged into one in each ri (the lowest administrative unit), and the chairman


57


of the ri people’s committee is appointed concurrently the managerial chairman of the co-op.

This was the measure for bringing ri people’s com- mittees closer to production and raising their function and leadership over the economic and cultural construction in ri.


| Engels said that under socialism and Communism “the government of persons is replaced by the administra- tion of things, and by the conduct of processes of produc- tion.”


Naturally, under present conditions in our country “government of persons” is one of the important functions of the ri people’s committees. But it must also be noted that the function of “administering things and conducting processes of production” is being increasingly extended.

Our Party took into account such actual conditions in merging agricultural co-operatives into one in each ri and appointing the chairman of ri people’s committee con- currently the managerial chairman of a co-op.

In amalgamating agricultural co-operatives, our Par- ty transferred the management of rural consumers’ co- operative stores and credit co-operatives which had _ ex- ercised their function independently in each ri to the agri- cultural co-operatives.

This enables the agricultural co-operatives to organ- ize and manage under a unified plan all economic affairs from production to. distribution, exchange and consumption, thereby accelerating the process of reproduction and further improving the wellbeing of co-op members.

This is to meet the objective requirements for enhancing the material interest of peasants and harvest- ing farm produce in greater abundance by further promot- ing marketing of commodities and money circulation in the countryside.

Next, with the amalgamation, the range of activities of agricultural co-operatives grew. Besides economic man- agement, they now undertake educational, cullural, public health and public welfare work,


58


This means that our agricultural co-operatives no

longer confine themselves merely to economic matters, but pay attention to the whole aspects of peasants’ life and assume responsibility for their life. _ The extension of the range of activity of co-ops was to meet the earnest desire of our peasants, who, subjected to onerous oppression and exploitation for centuries, had been most backward, to raise rapidly their cultural stand- ard.

In this way, the Government, while conducting uni- fied guidance over education, entrusts agricultural co-ops with the management of schools.

This makes it possible to expand speedily the network of schools of all levels, with little state expenditure and, at the same time, this is of great significance for integrat- ing production with education.

In his report to the Twenty-first Extraordinary Con- gress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union, Com- rade N.S. Khrushchov particularly stressed the necessity of gradually transferring functions of government organs to social organizations. And this is now being practised in the Soviet Union.

It is to meet the demands arising in the development of socialist society towards Communism that in our coun- try the state has transferred much of its work to agri- cultural co-operatives.

Organization of educational, cultural, public health and public welfare work by agricultural co-operatives is of particular significance for the growth of communist ele- ments in the countryside.

When educational, cultural, public health and public welfare establishments are provided to co-op members free of charge for, as Marx noted, “the common satisfac- tion of needs,” they are all embryos of Communism.

Management of educational, cultural, public health and public welfare work by agricultural co-ops is of great significance in preparing for the building of Communism.

The National Congress of Agricultural Co-operatives held in January 1959, summed up the great victory in the socialist agricultural co-operativization in our country,


59


set forth the tasks for further development of agriculture and, at the same time, adopted new Standard Rules of agricultural co-operatives.

With a view to hastening the completion of socialist construction in the countryside and gradually preparing for the building of Communist society, the new Standard Rules provide for the further extending and strengthening of the socialist co-operative ownership of the means of production and the turning of them into ownership by the whole people. |

Agricultural co-operativization was completed and the third form, fully socialist, became the sole form of agricultural co-operatives and share is distributed accord- ing to the work done. On this basis, the Standard Rules proclaimed land and all other means of production as the socialist co-operative ownership.

The Standard Rules put an end to the private owner- ship of land which had existed for several thousand years and which was legally permitted even in the co-op of the third form. All land owned by co-op members are brought under common ownership according to the new Standard Rules, and this is an epoch-making event in the historical development in our country.

In the early days of the agricultural co-operative movement, co-op members were allowed to some extent to own privately draft animals and farm implements, when they so desired, and in such case these were used jointly by co-op members. But according to the new Standard Rules draft animals and farm implements are placed un- der common ownership, and the scale of side-line privately run by co-op members and the acreage of kitchen garden for co-op members were reduced markedly.

The aim of developing the co-operative ownership in- to public ownership and the line of applying socialist principle in production and distribution of share and pro- moting Communist co-operation are laid down in the Standard Rules.

The agricultural co-operative movement in our coun- try has gone through the experimental stage, mass devel- opment stage and the stage of completion in its progress,


60


These stages were determined by the different speed and form of the movement. Therefore, they do not repre- sent any changes of co-ops in their quality and character.

Viewed from the point of social and economic devel- opment, the five years of the progress of our agricultural co-operative movement from the experimental stage to the stage of completion was a historic period when the private ownership of the means of production was converted into co-operative ownership and exclusive dominance of the socialist agriculture was established in the countryside.

The past five years was a period of sweeping revolu- lionary transformation of production relations, a period, as Comrade Kim Il Sung noted, marked by the rapid de- velopment of productive forces, further consolidation of the co-operative economy, swift improvement of peasants’ life and the high spirit of our peasants. During this period, the foundation was laid for developing our agriculture to a higher stage.

The position of our agricultural co-operatives has been radically changed. Our agricultural co-operatives are iow in a position to introduce gradually up-to-date machines and technique into their common economy. Moreover, the agricultural co-operatives are not related with the private capitalist elements and small commodity products, as the agricultural co-operativization and soci- alist transformation of private commerce and industry were completed simultaneously.

In production and supply of commodities, our agricul- {ural co-ops deal only with state-operated bodies and enterprises and are related with other co-operative economy.

The character of our agricultural co-operative econo- my has undergone changes and developed in many spheres. Our co-ops today are different from and far more advanced than the co-ops of the third form.

This progress was not made in a day.

Our agricultural co-ops underwent constant quantita- tive and qualitative changes in the course of its develop- ment. The progress of our agricultural co-ops has been made possible not only by the changes and development


61


within agriculture itself but also by the all-round changes and development of our society and economy.

With the changes in the scale and character of agricul- tural co-operatives—this represents a stage of fresh pro- press of the agricultural co-operative economy—brighter prospects are opened up for the development of agricultural productive forces in our country.

For Further Upsurge in Agriculture

A high tide of socialist construction is sweeping our country, and the entire working people are pressing ahead on a winged horse, in response to Party’s call.

The First Five-Year Plan (1957-61) under which the total value of industrial output is to increase 2.6 times, is expected to be fulfilled within 1959, more than two years ahead of schedule.

During the first two years of the current First Five- an Plan, that is, in 1957 and 1958, our industrial output

oubled.


On the occasion of the tenth anniversary of the Demo- cratic People’s Republic of Korea in September 1958, our Party, on the basis of the achievements in socialist con- struction and the high revolutionary zeal of the working people, advanced prospective tasks of turning our country into an advanced socialist industrial country.

The prospective tasks envisage a big leap forward in the production of major industrial products in the next six or seven years: output of electric power, is to increase 2.6 times; coal, 3.6 times; pig iron and granulated iron, 9 times; steel, 8-9 times; cement, 4 times; chemical fertiliz- ers, 3.3-4.3 times; and fabrics, 4.6 times.

When these tasks are carried out, the per capita out- put of electric power will reach 2,000 kwh, coal 2,500 kg, pig iron and granulated iron 400 kg., steel 300-350 kg., cement 500 kg., chemical fertilizers 150-200 kg., and fabrics more than 50 metres,

Determined to carry out the huge tasks presented by the Party earlier than scheduled, our working people are


63


displaying inexhaustible creative energy in their strenuous endeavour.


In order to hasten the completion of socialist construc- tion and preparations for gradually going over to Com- munism, our agriculture must keep pace with the rapidly developing indusiry.

The primary tasks now confronting our agriculture are to accomplish the technical and cultural revolutions in the near future and thereby further strengthen and develop politically apd economically the socialist co-operative eco- nomy and turn our rural villages into rich, modern, soci- alist villages where modern technique is employed in the farming.


Material and technical foundation of our agriculture has been strengthened considerably, but the technical reform was lagging behind the economic transformation,


Until now our agricultural co-operatives have dis- played their superiority primarily on the basis of handicraft technique. But today our agricultural co-ops find it im- possible to ensure a bigger upsurge in production, unless they are furnished with modern technique.


It is clear that our advanced socialist co-operative economy can no longer base itself on backward handicrait technique. Therefore, the technical revolution, with the building of irrigation systems, mechanization and electri- fication as its main contents, is presented as the most urgent and central task of our agriculture.


The completion of agricultural co-operativization, ex- tension of the scale of the co-operatives, consolidation of their economic foundation and the building up of the bases of heavy industry—all this presents the technical revolu- tion in the countryside as matured task. Consequently, our Party set the following targets: putting the entire arable land under irrigation within 2-3 years, mechanization of agriculture within 4-5 years, electrification within 1-2 years. And the state took steps for mobilizing agricultural co- operatives for successfully implementing these tasks.


64


While the construction of big-scale irrigation projects and work on the hydro-power stations were undertaken with state funds, the Party has encouraged the agricultural co-operatives to build medium- and small-scale irrigation projects and power stations. Then the Party saw to it that the co-ops with sufficient economic foundation should secure modern machinery and equipment including tractors and lorries.


Such measures are the manifestation of the Leninist principle on the full display of the creativeness and active- ness of popular masses in socialist construction.


Irrigation is the keynote of the technical revolution

in our agriculture, Irrigation is of decisive significance in increasing agricultural products under the condition in which rice cultivation on paddy-fields holds a most im- portant place and a long drought and frequent floods occur in spring and summer. _ Indeed, Lenin’s words that “irrigation is needed, a- bove all, as it transforms or revives the border region, buries the past, and accelerating the transition to social- ism” fully meets with the reality of our country. (Lenin’s Collected Works, Vol. 32, Russian ed. p. 297.)


Now that the irrigation of paddy fields has been, in the main, completed thanks to the consistent measures taken by the Party for the expansion of the acreage under irrigation, the cardinal task of irrigation lies in rapidly establishing the non-paddy irrigation system.


Only by doing so can we swiftly increase grain harvest on the non-paddy fields which occupy over two thirds ol the arable land and at the same time develop simultane- ously and on a full scale the branches of industrial crops, stock-breeding, pomiculture and sericulture.


The September (1958) Plenum of the Central Com- mittee of our Party set forth the task of completing the irrigation system on all arable land with the exception of steep slopes within the next 2 or 3 years.

Already over 10,000 projects, including the state


65


sponsored big-scale irrigation project in Kiyang (the acre- age under irrigation will cover 51,000 jungbo), Ujidon (34,000 jungbo) and in the Yalu River basin (95,000 jung- bo), are under way. During the past 6 months from the September (1958) Plenum to the spring of this year, reser- voirs, pumping stations and other irrigation facilities for irrigating 377,000 jungbo were built. As a result, by the end of June 1959 the total acreage of irrigated land in our country had reached over 800,000 jungbo. Thus, the nation- 7 task of irrigation in the countryside has been fulfilled in e main.


Remarkable success has also been attained in the field of mechanization of farm work.


The many-sided development of agriculture, wide ap- plication of the advanced intensive farming methods, un- dertaking of big-scale irrigation projects and other rural construction and the sharp increase in the volume of transport that followed co-operativization—all this brought about an acute shortage of labour, farm machines and transport facilities in the countryside.


Without mechanization of major farming and tran- sport work the continuous growth of agricultural produc- tion and vast scale construction could not be successfully ensured.

The acreage of farm land (excluding slopes with a 12 degree gradient, swamps and siony fields), on which mechanization can be introduced, amounts to some 1,400,000 jungbo.

At least 30,000-35,000 tractors and 25,000-30,000 lor- ries are needed for the overall mechanization of basic farming work and heavy transport work in the rural areas.

This year 5,000 tractors and 2,500 lorries will be sent to the countryside, most of which will be Korean-make. And within the coming 4-5 years the need for tractors and lorries will be fully met.

A number of agricultural co-ops have already pur- chased tractors and lorries and the network of farm ma- chine hire stations continues to expand. The number of farm machine hire stations increased from 59 to 80,


66


So far, the agricultural co-ops used modern farm machines of the state farm machine hire station, But in future the co-operatives will possess modern farm machines fcr themselves.

Many ex-servicemen and the junior and senior middle school graduates who had worked in the co-ops have been dispatched to farm machine hire stations and state farms to be trained as tractor drivers and mechanics. In this way, the mechanized work teams have been organized in the co-ops, and a full scale readjusting of fields is now in progress.

It is expected in the coming 2 or 3 years labour power needed in the rural areas will increase at least 2-fold.

Hence, it is the urgent problem to raise rapidly lab- our productivity by widely introducing medium- and small-scale mechanization in combination with large-scale mechanization.

In our agriculture, paddy-field farming holds an im- portant place. The land is undulated and slopes are very steep. Intensive cultivation such as mixed-crop and furrow cullivations has been in long practice. The differences of natural and economic conditions vary greatly according to the localities. Accordingly, it is of great significance to con- trive and popularize various kinds of farm machines, parti- cularly, simple medium and small farm implements suit- able to the actual condition.

For the completion of irrigation and mechanization in ie countryside, electrification should be pushed ahead ol -hem.

According to the preliminary investigation, for elec- trification of the countryside 920 million kwh of elec- tricity will be needed, 5 times more than the power the countryside consumes at present. It is estimated that big power stations will supply 580 million kwh while the re- maining 340 million kwh will be produced at 8,600 medium and small power stations of agricultural co-ops. These co- op power stations will have a capacity of 20 kw on an average.

At present, the construction of medium- and small- scale power stations in every rural village along with such


67


big-scale hydropower stations as Dokrogang, Kangge and Woonbong, is being pushed ahead briskly.

Our country is abundantly endowed with water power and other electric resources. And the construction of large-scale water conservancy projects have been carried out. Thus favourable conditions are provided for power generation.

Already more than 800 power stations had been built during the four months from September 1958 when the construction of medium- and small-scale power stations started in the countryside.

It is planned that this year the rural villages will be supplied with ‘equipment and machinery to build some 6,000 medium- and small-scale power stations. Then the electrification of the countryside will be completed in the main by 1960.

Proceeding from the fact that the foundation of co- operatives has been consolidated and the living standard of the co-operative members as a whole improved, the new Standard Rules of the co-operatives provide for raising the common reserve funds from ‘10-15 per cent to 15-30 per cent or more for the successful implementation of technical revolution.

In the meantime, the Party and Government took steps to help the co-operatives increase their accumulations.

From January 1, 1959, the rate of taxes-in-kind was lowered from 20.1 per cent to 8.4 per cent on an average, and its amount is fixed. And it will eventually be abolished in the future.

It has been the consistent line of our Party io develop a diversified agriculture with the stress on the grain pro- duction, widely introducing the advanced intensive farm- ing methods and actively pushing forward irrigation pro- jects, mechanization and electrification in the countryside.

Our Party put forward the militant tasks of increasing the output of farm produce in the near fulure: grain to 7 million tons, cotton to 200,000 tons, meat to 400,000 tons, cocoons to 60,000-70,000 tons, fruit to over 250,000 tons. These figures show an increase of some 2 times in grain, 4 times in cotton, 4.4 times in meat, 8 times in cocoons and


68


2 times in fruit compared with 1958, In this way, our rural ae will provide a rich food base and a raw material ase.

Only with such rapid development of agricultural pro- duction in a diversified way, it was possible to eradicate completely the backwardness and onesidedness seen in our agricultural production, to bring about balanced develop- ment of industry and agriculture, to meet the varying re- quirements of the population, and to raise the income of cooperative members. In the past, our agriculture concen- trated exclusively on raising the grain crops and failed to solve even this.

Now that the grain problem has been solved and the technical transformation of agriculture is being carried out on full scale, favourable conditions for developing the co- operative economy in a diversified way have been created.

Our Party has set the tasks of raising paddy rice out- put per jungbo to 10-15 tons, maize to 4-5 tons, wheat to 3-4 tons, and cotton to 3-4 tons within the coming 2 or 3 years.

To this end, wide application of the advanced intensive farming methods—irrigation, deep ploughing, close plant- ing, liberal fertilizing and sowing of best-quality seeds—is most important.

In the light of the fact that the acreage of arable land in our country is limited, such intensive farming methods are of decisive significance.

If we plough more than 30 cm deep (10 cm in the past), apply an average of 500 kg of chemical fertilizers per jungbo (200 kg in the past) and 50 tons of compost (10 tons in the past) within the next 2 or 3 years and further raise planting density of all crops, harvest can be immen- sely increased.

The cold-bed rice seedling method which is a great technical innovation in the cultivation of paddy rice should be developed further. If 300 seedlings are planted to one pyong, each seedling will sprout 6 branches and each ear will bear 80 grains of rice on an average, Taking the weight of 1,000 grains as 25 grams, the per pyong yield will reach 3.6 kg or 10.8 tons per jungbo. A harvest ot


69


more than 5 million tons of rice can be expected from only 900,000 jungbo, Then pcople will be supplied more than enough with rice and flour as their principal food.

In 1958 there were some co-ops, that harvested 55 tons of rice per jungbo, 18 tons of maize, 4.5 tons of wheat, 6.7 tons of cotton. And it can be safely said that these high yields can be surpassed.

To cite one example:

The Dooam Agricultural Co-operative, Kangnam County, South Pyongan Province, gathered 55 tons of paddy rice per jungbo on a 1.5 jungbo experimental plot. To do this they ploughed the field only 20 cm deep, applied 75 tons of compost per jtuungbo and transplanted 133 cold- bed seedlings per pyong. But suppose they plough 30 cm deep, apply 100-200 tons of compost and transplant over 250 cold-bed seedlings, there is no doubt that the per jungbo yield of rice will go yet higher.

The same thing is true with maize, wheat, cotton and other crops.


In the field of stock-breeding, too, our Party set the tasks of increasing the number of domestic animals: cows from 660,000 to one million, pigs from 1.4 million to four million, sheep and goats from 150,000 to 600,000-700,000. These figures will be attained within the next two or three years, while raising the annual output of meat to 400,000 tons, milk to 460,000 tons and eggs to 1.5 billion. Thus, per capita production of meat will be 40 kg, milk 46 ke and eggs 150.

For the rapid development of stock-breeding, the most lagging field in our agriculture, main efforts have been concentrated on the joint stock-breeding by the -o-opera- tives and on establishing firm fodder bases. For this pur- pose two-crop cultivation will be extensively introduced and fodder fields will be expanded to 500,000-600,000 jungbo in 3-4 years.

A number of measures have been taken to bring about a new change in sericulture, pomiculture and apiculture and in fresh-water fish breeding.

While emphasizing the development of agricultural


70


production, our Party is actively promoting rural construc- tion, above all, productive construction.

Office buildings, building material production estab- lishments, metal-working shops, wood-working shops, warehouses, facilities for processing agricultural products will be built in the countryside. Furthermore, it is expected that within the next 4 or 5 years 800,000 dwelling houses, school buildings with over 2,800 class rooms besides kin- dergartens, creches, clubs, hospitals, restaurants, stores, bath houses and cultural establishments will be built or improved.

It is also expected that by 1963 the amount of common reserve funds of all agricultural co-operatives throughout the country will stand approximately at 4.4 billion won. Only some 700 million won, that is, 16 per cent of the total amount of common reserve funds, will be needed to build all these schools, dwelling houses and cultural facilities. This bespeaks that our agricultural co-operatives can carry out the cultural construction programme in parallel with the productive construction.

In the meantime, by 1961 per household share will reach over 2 tons of grain and over 1,000 won in cash on an average. This will enable all the co-operative members to purchase a modern dwelling house on easy terms.

The basic task of the cultural revolution for raising the level of general knowledge and technology of the entire

easants is also being successfully carried out.

The compulsory three-year middle school education system has been put into effect, starting from November 1958 and the universal compulsory two-year technical edu- cation system will be enforced in the very near future.

The preparatory work for enforcing the universal com- pulsory technical education system ahead of schedule is now going full fledge in every rural village, while teachers for technical schools are being trained in special courses attached to the higher educational institutions and higher technical schools.

At the same time, large numbers of co-operative mem- bers are studying in working people’s schools and working people’s middle schools which were set up to raise the


71


general educational level of the entire peasants above the level of the elementary school or junior middle school eraduates.

All these facts indicate that the tasks of the cultural revolution in our country are being successfully carried out.


* *K *« 


Today the entire peasants of our country have risen up as one for the implementation of the programmatic tasks laid down by Premier Kim Il Sung at the National Con- press of Agricultural Co-operatives and the entire working class is giving powerful support to them.

In the course of discussing the Letter of the Party Central Committee sent to the entire Party members in September, last year, and the measures for implementing the tasks set forth at the National Congress of Agricultural Co-operatives, the revolutionary enthusiasm and creative activeness of farmers have been heightened more than ever.

They have set up higher targets for increased produc. ticn than the state plan and are putting up a strenuous struggle to carry them out.

There is no shadow of doubt that our co-operative members will victoriously carry out, under the correct guidance of the Workers’ Party of Korea and with the powerful support of the working class, the magnificent plan for socialist rural construction drawn up by the Cen- tral Committee of the Workers’ Party of Korea headed by Comrade Kim I] Sung.

The harder our peasants work, the higher the produc- tive forces will rise. The higher the productive forces rise, the sooner we will reach the eminence of socialism.

Looking forward to the bright future leading to Com- munist society where the principle of “from each according to his ability, to each according to his needs” operates, our peasants are marching vigorously toward Com- munism.